Ineconomics,anaggregateis a summarymeasure.It replaces avectorthat is composed of manyreal numbersby a single real number, or ascalar.Consequently, there occur various problems that are inherent in the formulations that use aggregated variables.[1]
Theaggregation problemis the difficult problem of finding a valid way to treat anempiricalor theoretical aggregate as if it reacted like a less-aggregated measure, say, about behavior of an individualagentas described in generalmicroeconomic theory[1](seerepresentative agentandheterogeneity in economics).
The second meaning of "aggregation problem" is the theoretical difficulty in using and treating laws and theorems that include aggregate variables. A typical example is theaggregate production function.[2]Another famous problem isSonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu theorem.Most of macroeconomic statements comprise this problem.
Examples of aggregates in micro- andmacroeconomicsrelative to less aggregated counterparts are:
- Food vs. apples
- Price levelandreal GDPvs. the price and quantity of apples
- Capital stockvs. the value of computers of a certain type and the value ofsteam shovels
- Money supplyvs. paper currency
- Generalunemployment ratevs. the unemployment rate of civil engineers
Standard theory uses simple assumptions to derive general, and commonly accepted, results such as thelaw of demandto explain market behavior. An example is the abstraction of acomposite good.It considers the price of one good changing proportionately to the composite good, that is, all other goods. If this assumption is violated and the agents are subject to aggregatedutility functions,restrictions on the latter are necessary to yield the law of demand. The aggregation problem emphasizes:
- How broad such restrictions are in microeconomics
- Use of broad factor inputs ( "labor" and "capital" ), real "output", and "investment", as if there was only a single such aggregate is without a solid foundation for rigorously deriving analytical results.
Franklin Fishernotes that this has not dissuaded macroeconomists from continuing to use such concepts.[1]
Aggregate consumer demand curve
editThe aggregate consumerdemand curveis the summation of the individual consumer demand curves. The aggregation process preserves only two characteristics of individualconsumer preference theory—continuity and homogeneity. Aggregation introduces three additional non-price determinants of demand:
- Number of consumers
- Distribution of tastes among the consumers
- Distribution of incomes among consumers of different taste
Thus if the population of consumers increases,ceteris paribusthe demand curve will shift out; if the proportion of consumers with a strong preference for a good increases, ceteris paribus the demand for that good will change. Finally, if thedistribution of incomechanges in favor of consumers who prefer the good in question, the demand will shift out. It is important to remember that factors that affect individual demand can also affect aggregate demand. However, net effects must be considered. The most important problem for micro- and macro-economics is theSonnenschein–Mantel–Debreu theorem,which shows that almost no properties of the individual preference are inherited to the aggregate demand functions.[3][4][5]
Difficulties with aggregation
editSonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu theorem
editSonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu theorem(SMD theorem) is a theorem for exchange economy that can be expressed in the following way:
for a function that is continuous, homogeneous of degree zero, and in accord with Walras's law,there is an economy with at least as many agents as goods such that, for prices bounded away from zero, the function is the aggregate demand function for this economy.[4]
Independence assumption
editFirst, to sum the demand functions without other strong assumptions it must be assumed that they are independent – that is, that one consumer's demand decisions are not influenced by the decisions of another consumer.[6]For example, A is asked how many pairs of shoes he would buy at a certain price. A says at that price I would be willing and able to buy two pairs of shoes. B is asked the same question and says four pairs. Questioner goes back to A and says B is willing to buy four pairs of shoes, what do you think about that? A says if B has any interest in those shoes then I have none. Or A, not to be outdone by B, says "then I'll buy five pairs". And on and on. This problem can be eliminated by assuming that the consumers' tastes are fixed in the short run. This assumption can be expressed as assuming that each consumer is an independent idiosyncratic decision maker.
No interesting properties
editThis second problem is more serious. AsDavid M. Krepsnotes, “total demand will shift about as a function of how individual incomes are distributed even holding total (societal) income fixed. So it makes no sense to speak ofaggregate demandas a function of price and societal income ".[7]Since any change inrelative pricebrings about a redistribution of real income, there is a separate demand curve for every relative price. Kreps continues, "So what can we say about aggregate demand based on the hypothesis that individuals are preference/utility maximizers? Unless we are able to make strong assumptions about the distribution of preferences or income throughout the economy (everyone has the samehomothetic preferencesfor example) there is little we can say”.[7]The strong assumptions are that everyone has the same tastes and that each person's tastes remain the same as income changes so additional income is spent in exactly the same way as before.
MicroeconomistHal Varianreached a more muted conclusion: "The aggregate demand function will in general possess no interesting properties".[8]However, Varian continued: "theneoclassical theoryof the consumer places no restriction onaggregate behaviorin general ".[8]This means the preference conditions (with the possible exception of continuity) simply do not apply to the aggregate function.
See also
editNotes
edit- ^abcFranklin M. Fisher (1987). "aggregation problem,"The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics,v. 1, pp.53-55
- ^J. Felipe & J.S.L. McCombie (2014) The Aggregate Production Function: 'Not Even Wrong.'Review of Political Economy26(1): 60-84.
- ^S. Abu Turab Rizvi (1994) The microfoundations project in general equilibrium theory.Cambridge Journal of Economics18(4): 357-377.
- ^abA. Abu Turab Rizivi (2006) "The Sonnenschein-Matel-Dereu Results after Thirty Years."History of Political Economy38(Suppl_1): 228–245.http://ebour.com.ar/pdfs/Rizvi%20The%20Sonnenschein%20Mantel%20Debreu%20Results%20after%20Thirty%20Years.pdf"
- ^Alan Kirman (1989) "The Intrinsic Limits of Modern Economic Theory: The Emperor has No Clothes."Economic Journal99(395) Supplement: Conference Papers: 126-139.
- ^Besanko and Braeutigam, (2005) p. 169
- ^abKreps (1990) p. 63.
- ^abVarian (1992) p. 153.
References
edit- Franklin M. Fisher(1987). "aggregation problem,"The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics,v. 1, pp. 53–55.
- Jesus Felipe and Franklin M. Fisher (2008). "aggregation (production),"The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics,2nd Edition.Abstract.
- John R. Hicks(1939, 2nd ed. 1946).Value and Capital.
- Werner Hildenbrand(2008). "aggregation (theory),"The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics,2nd Edition.Abstract.
- Thomas M. Stoker (2008). "aggregation (econometrics),"The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics,2nd Edition.Abstract.
- Douglas W. Blackburn and Andrey D. Ukhov (2008) "Individual vs. Aggregate Preferences: The Case of a Small Fish in a Big Pond,"Abstract.