Fixed exchange rate system

Afixed exchange rate,often called apegged exchange rate,is a type ofexchange rate regimein which acurrency's value is fixed or pegged by amonetary authorityagainst the value of another currency, abasket of other currencies,or another measure of value, such asgold.

There are benefits and risks to using a fixed exchange rate system. A fixed exchange rate is typically used to stabilize the exchange rate of a currency by directly fixing its value in a predetermined ratio to a different, more stable, or more internationally prevalent currency (or currencies) to which the currency is pegged. In doing so, the exchange rate between the currency and its peg does not change based on market conditions, unlike in afloating (flexible) exchange regime.This makes trade and investments between the two currency areas easier and more predictable and is especially useful for small economies that borrow primarily in foreign currency and in which external trade forms a large part of theirGDP.

A fixed exchange rate system can also be used to control the behavior of a currency, such as by limiting rates ofinflation.However, in doing so, the pegged currency is then controlled by its reference value. As such, when the reference value rises or falls, it then follows that the values of any currencies pegged to it will also rise and fall in relation to other currencies and commodities with which the pegged currency can be traded. In other words, a pegged currency is dependent on its reference value to dictate how its current worth is defined at any given time. In addition, according to theMundell–Fleming model,with perfectcapitalmobility, a fixed exchange rate prevents a government from using domesticmonetary policyto achievemacroeconomicstability.

In a fixed exchange rate system, a country'scentral banktypically uses an open market mechanism and is committed at all times to buy and sell its currency at a fixed price in order to maintain its pegged ratio and, hence, the stable value of its currency in relation to the reference to which it is pegged. To maintain a desired exchange rate, the central bank during a time of private sector net demand for the foreign currency, sells foreign currency from its reserves and buys back the domestic money. This creates an artificialdemandfor the domestic money, which increases its exchange rate value. Conversely, in the case of an incipient appreciation of the domestic money, the central bank buys back the foreign money and thus adds domestic money into the market, thereby maintaining market equilibrium at the intended fixed value of the exchange rate.[1]

In the 21st century, the currencies associated with large economies typically do not fix (peg) their exchange rates to other currencies. The last large economy to use a fixed exchange rate system was thePeople's Republic of China,which, in July 2005, adopted a slightly more flexible exchange rate system, called amanaged exchange rate.[2]TheEuropean Exchange Rate Mechanismis also used on a temporary basis to establish a final conversion rate against theeurofrom the local currencies of countries joining theEurozone.[3][4][5]

History

edit

Chronology

edit

Timeline of the fixed exchange rate system:[6]

1880–1914 Classical gold standard period
April 1925 United Kingdom returns to gold standard
October 1929 United States stock market crashes
September 1931 United Kingdom abandons gold standard
July 1944 Bretton Woods conference
March 1947 International Monetary Fundcomes into being
August 1971 United Statessuspends convertibilityof dollar into gold – Bretton Woods system collapses
December 1971 Smithsonian Agreement
March 1972 European snakewith 2.25% band of fluctuation allowed
March 1973 Managed float regimecomes into being
April 1978 Jamaica Accordstake effect
September 1985 Plaza Accord
September 1992 United Kingdom andItalyabandonExchange Rate Mechanism(ERM)
August 1993 European Monetary Systemallows ±15% fluctuation in exchange rates

Gold standard

edit

Bretton Woods system

edit

Current monetary regimes

edit

Mechanisms

edit

Open market trading

edit

Typically, a government wanting to maintain a fixed exchange rate does so by either buying or selling its own currency on the open market.[7]This is one reason governments maintain reserves of foreign currencies.

If the exchange rate drifts too far above the fixed benchmark rate (it is stronger than required), the government sells its own currency (which increases supply) and buys foreign currency. This causes the price of the currency to decrease in value (Read: Classical Demand-Supply diagrams). Also, if they buy the currency it is pegged to, then the price of that currency will increase, causing the relative value of the currencies to approach what is intended.

If the exchange rate drifts too far below the desired rate, the government buys its own currency in the market by selling its reserves. This places greater demand on the market and causes the local currency to become stronger, hopefully back to its intended value. The reserves they sell may be the currency it is pegged to, in which case the value of that currency will fall.

Fiat

edit

Another, less used means of maintaining a fixed exchange rate is by simply making it illegal to trade currency at any other rate. This is difficult to enforce and often leads to ablack marketin foreign currency. Nonetheless, some countries are highly successful at using this method due to government monopolies over all money conversion. This was the method employed by the Chinese government to maintain a currency peg or tightly banded float against the US dollar. China buys an average of one billion US dollars a day to maintain the currency peg.[8]Throughout the 1990s, China was highly successful at maintaining a currency peg using a government monopoly over all currency conversion between the yuan and other currencies.[9][10][11]

Open market mechanism example

edit
Fig.1: Mechanism of fixed exchange-rate system

Excess demand for dollars

edit
Fig.2: Excess demand for dollars

Excess supply of dollars

edit
Fig.3: Excess supply of dollars

Types of fixed exchange rate systems

edit

The gold standard

edit

The gold standard is the pegging of money to a certain amount of gold.

Price specie flow mechanism

edit

Reserve currency standard

edit

Currency boardarrangements are the most widespread means of fixed exchange rates. Currency boards are considered hard pegs as they allow central banks to cope with shocks to money demand without running out of reserves.[12]CBAs have been operational in many nations including:

Gold exchange standard

edit

Hybrid exchange rate systems

edit
De factoexchange-rate arrangements in 2022 as classified by theInternational Monetary Fund.
Floating(floatingandfree floating)
Soft pegs (conventional peg,stabilized arrangement,crawling peg,crawl-like arrangement,pegged exchange rate within horizontal bands)
Residual (other managed arrangement)

Basket-of-currencies

edit

Crawling pegs

edit

Pegged within a band

edit

Currency boards

edit

Currency substitution

edit

Monetary co-operation

edit

Monetary co-operation is the mechanism in which two or moremonetary policiesorexchange ratesare linked, and can happen at regional or international level.[15]The monetary co-operation does not necessarily need to be a voluntary arrangement between two countries, as it is also possible for a country to link itscurrencyto another countries currency without theconsentof the other country. Various forms of monetary co-operations exist, which range from fixed parity systems tomonetary unions.Also, numerous institutions have been established to enforce monetary co-operation and to stabiliseexchange rates,including theEuropean Monetary Cooperation Fund(EMCF) in 1973[16]and theInternational Monetary Fund(IMF)[17][unreliable source]

Monetary co-operation is closely related toeconomic integration,and are often considered to be reinforcing processes.[18]However, economic integration is an economic arrangement between different regions, marked by the reduction or elimination oftrade barriersand the coordination of monetary andfiscal policies,[19]whereas monetary co-operation is focussed on currency linkages. Amonetary unionis considered to be the crowning step of a process of monetary co-operation andeconomic integration.[18]In the form of monetary co-operation where two or more countries engage in a mutually beneficial exchange,capitalamong the countries involved is free to move, in contrast tocapital controls.[18]Monetary co-operation is considered to promote balancedeconomic growthand monetary stability,[20]but can also work counter-effectively if the member countries have (strongly) differing levels ofeconomic development.[18]Especially European and Asian countries have a history of monetary and exchange rate co-operation,[21]however the European monetary co-operation and economic integration eventually resulted in aEuropean monetary union.

Example: The Snake

edit

In 1973, the currencies of theEuropean Economic Communitycountries, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Luxemburg and the Netherlands, participated in an arrangement calledthe Snake.This arrangement is categorized as exchange rate co-operation. During the next 6 years, this agreement allowed the currencies of the participating countries tofluctuatewithin a band of plus or minus 2¼% around pre-announcedcentral rates.Later, in 1979, theEuropean Monetary System(EMS) was founded, with the participating countries in‘the Snake’being founding members. The EMS evolves over the next decade and even results into a trulyfixed exchange rateat the start of the 1990s.[18]Around this time, in 1990, theEUintroduced theEconomic and Monetary Union(EMU), as an umbrella term for the group of policies aimed at converging theeconomiesof member states of theEuropean Unionover three phases[22]

Example: The baht-U.S. dollar co-operation

edit

In 1963, the Thai government established the Exchange Equalization Fund (EEF) with the purpose of playing a role in stabilizing exchange rate movements. It linked to theU.S. dollarby fixing the amount of gram ofgoldperbahtas well as the baht per U.S. dollar. Over the course of the next 15 years, the Thai government decided todepreciatethe baht in terms of gold three times, yet maintain theparityof the baht against the U.S. dollar. Due to the introduction of a new generalized floating exchange rate system by theInternational Monetary Fund(IMF) in 1978 that gave a smaller role to gold in the international monetary system, this fixed parity system as a monetary co-operation policy was terminated. The Thai government amended its monetary policies to be more in line with the new IMF policy.[18]

Fixed exchange rate system advantage

edit

Disadvantages

edit

Lack of automatic rebalancing

edit

One main criticism of a fixed exchange rate is that flexible exchange rates serve to adjust thebalance of trade.[23]When a trade deficit occurs under a floating exchange rate, there will be increased demand for the foreign (rather than domestic) currency which will push up the price of the foreign currency in terms of the domestic currency. That in turn makes the price of foreign goods less attractive to the domestic market and thus pushes down the trade deficit. Under fixed exchange rates, this automatic rebalancing does not occur.

Currency crisis

edit

Another major disadvantage of a fixed exchange-rate regime is the possibility of the central bank running out of foreign exchange reserves when trying to maintain the peg in the face of demand for foreign reserves exceeding their supply. This is called acurrency crisisor balance of payments crisis, and when it happens the central bank mustdevaluethe currency. When there is the prospect of this happening, private-sector agents will try to protect themselves by decreasing their holdings of the domestic currency and increasing their holdings of the foreign currency, which has the effect of increasing the likelihood that the forced devaluation will occur. A forced devaluation will change the exchange rate by more than the day-by-day exchange rate fluctuations under a flexible exchange rate system.

Freedom to conduct monetary and fiscal policy

edit

Moreover, a government, when having a fixed rather than dynamic exchange rate, cannot use monetary or fiscal policies with a free hand. For instance, by using reflationary tools to set the economy growing faster (by decreasing taxes and injecting more money in the market), the government risks running into a trade deficit. This might occur as the purchasing power of a common household increases along with inflation, thus making imports relatively cheaper.[citation needed]

Additionally, the stubbornness of a government in defending a fixed exchange rate when in atrade deficitwill force it to use deflationary measures (increased taxation and reduced availability of money), which can lead tounemployment.Finally, other countries with a fixed exchange rate can also retaliate in response to a certain country using the currency of theirs in defending their exchange rate.[citation needed]

Fixed exchange rate regime versus capital control

edit

The belief that thefixed exchange rate regimebrings with it stability is only partly true, sincespeculative attackstend to target currencies with fixed exchange rate regimes, and in fact, the stability of the economic system is maintained mainly throughcapital control.A fixed exchange rate regime should be viewed as a tool in capital control.[neutralityisdisputed][citation needed]

FIX Line: Trade-off between symmetry of shocks and integration

edit
  • The trade-off between symmetry of shocks and market integration for countries contemplating a pegged currency is outlined in Feenstra and Taylor's 2015 publication "International Macroeconomics" through a model known as the FIX Line Diagram.
  • This symmetry-integration diagram features two regions, divided by a 45-degree line with slope of -1. This line can shift to the left or to the right depending on extra costs or benefits of floating. The line has slope= -1 is because the larger symmetry benefits are, the less pronounced integration benefits have to be and vice versa. The right region contains countries that have positive potential for pegging, while the left region contains countries that face significant risks and deterrents to pegging.
  • This diagram underscores the two main factors that drive a country to contemplate pegging a currency to another, shock symmetry and market integration. Shock symmetry can be characterized as two countries having similar demand shocks due to similar industry breakdowns and economies, while market integration is a factor of the volume of trading that occurs between member nations of the peg.
  • In extreme cases, it is possible for a country to only exhibit one of these characteristics and still have positive pegging potential. For example, a country that exhibits complete symmetry of shocks but has zero market integration could benefit from fixing a currency. The opposite is true, a country that has zero symmetry of shocks but has maximum trade integration (effectively one market between member countries). *This can be viewed on an international scale as well as a local scale. For example, neighborhoods within a city would experience enormous benefits from a common currency, while poorly integrated and dissimilar countries are likely to face large costs.

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^Dornbusch, Rüdiger;Fisher, Stanley;Startz, Richard (2011).Macroeconomics(Eleventh ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.ISBN978-0-07-337592-2.
  2. ^Goodman, Peter S. (2005-07-22)."China Ends Fixed-Rate Currency".The Washington Post.Archivedfrom the original on 2017-07-04.Retrieved2010-05-06.
  3. ^Cohen, Benjamin J, "Bretton Woods System",Routledge Encyclopedia of International Political Economy
  4. ^White, Lawrence.Is the Gold Standard Still the Gold Standard among Monetary Systems?,CATO Institute Briefing Paper no. 100, 8 Feb 2008
  5. ^Dooley, M.; Folkerts-Landau, D.; Garber, P. (2009)."Bretton Woods Ii Still Defines the International Monetary System"(PDF).Pacific Economic Review.14(3): 297–311.doi:10.1111/j.1468-0106.2009.00453.x.S2CID153352827.Archived(PDF)from the original on 2018-08-20.Retrieved2020-09-05.
  6. ^Salvatore, Dominick (2004).International Economics.John Wiley & Sons.ISBN978-81-265-1413-7.
  7. ^Ellie., Tragakes (2012).Economics for the IB Diploma(2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. p. 388.ISBN9780521186407.OCLC778243977.
  8. ^Cannon, M. (September 2016)."The Chinese Exchange Rate and Its Impact On The US Dollar".ForexWatchDog. Archived fromthe originalon 2017-12-03.Retrieved2016-10-04.
  9. ^Goodman, Peter S. (2005-07-27)."Don't Expect Yuan To Rise Much, China Tells World".The Washington Post.Archivedfrom the original on 2023-03-27.Retrieved2010-05-06.
  10. ^Griswold, Daniel (2005-06-25)."Protectionism No Fix for China's Currency".Cato Institute.Archivedfrom the original on 2023-02-03.Retrieved2010-05-06.
  11. ^O'Connell, Joan (1968). "An International Adjustment Mechanism with Fixed Exchange Rates".Economica.35(139): 274–282.doi:10.2307/2552303.JSTOR2552303.
  12. ^Feenstra, Robert C.; Taylor, Alan M. (2012).International Macroeconomics.New York: Worth.ISBN978-1429241038.
  13. ^Salvatore, Dominick; Dean, J; Willett,T.The Dollarisation Debate(Oxford University Press, 2003)
  14. ^Bordo, M. D.; MacDonald, R. (2003)."The inter-war gold exchange standard: Credibility and monetary independence"(PDF).Journal of International Money and Finance.22:1–32.doi:10.1016/S0261-5606(02)00074-8.S2CID154706279.Archived(PDF)from the original on 2018-06-02.Retrieved2019-12-11.
  15. ^Bergsten, C. F., & Green, R. A. (2016). Overview International Monetary Cooperation: Peterson Institute for International Economics
  16. ^European Monetary Cooperation Fund on Wikipedia
  17. ^Von Mises, L. (2010). International Monetary Cooperation. Mises Daily Articles. Retrieved fromhttps://mises.org/library/international-monetary-cooperationArchived2023-11-03 at theWayback Machine
  18. ^abcdefBerben, R.-P., Berk, J. M., Nitihanprapas, E., Sangsuphan, K., Puapan, P., & Sodsriwiboon, P. (2003). Requirements for successful currency regimes: The Dutch and Thai experiences: De Nederlandsche Bank
  19. ^"Economic Integration on Investopedia".Archivedfrom the original on 2018-02-01.Retrieved2016-12-06.
  20. ^James, H. (1996). International monetary cooperation since Bretton Woods: International Monetary Fund
  21. ^Volz, U. (2010). Introduction Prospects for Monetary Cooperation and Integration in East Asia. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press
  22. ^Economic and Monetary Union of the European Union on Wikipedia
  23. ^Suranovic, Steven (2008-02-14).International Finance Theory and Policy.Palgrave Macmillan. p. 504.