Semi-proportional representation

Semi-proportional representationcharacterizes multi-winnerelectoral systemswhich allow representation of minorities, but are not intended to reflect the strength of the competing political forces in close proportion to the votes they receive.[1]Semi-proportional voting systems are generally used as a compromise between complex and expensive but more-proportionalsystems (like thesingle transferable vote) and simplewinner-take-allsystems.[2][3]Examples of semi-proportional systems include thesingle non-transferable vote,limited voting,andparallel voting.

Semi-proportional systems

edit

Most proportional representation systems will not yield precisely proportional outcomes due to the use ofelection thresholds,small electoral regions, or other implementation details that vary from one elected body to another. However, systems that yield results close to the ideal are generally considered fully-proportional.

The choice to use a semi-proportional electoral system may be a deliberate attempt to find a balance between single-party rule and proportional representation. Semi-proportional systems can allow for fairer representation of those parties that have difficulty gaining even a single seat while retaining the possibility of one party gaining an overall majority of seats even if it receives less than a majority of the votes; they can ensure that the two or three largest parties all have their due share of seats or more while not producing representation for the smallest parties.

Because there are many measures of proportionality,[4][5]and because there is no objective threshold, opinions may differ on what constitutes a semi-proportional system as opposed to a non-proportional one or a fully proportional system.

Single-vote systems

edit

Election systems in which a party can achieve its due share of seats (proportionality) only by coordinating its voters are usually considered to be semi-proportional.[6]They are not non-proportional or majoritarian, since in the perfect case the outcome will be proportional, but they are not proportional either, since the perfect case is not guaranteed without coordination. Such systems include thesingle non-transferable voteandcumulative voting,both of which are commonly used to achieve approximately-proportional outcomes while maintaining simplicity and reducing the cost ofelection administration.Under these systems, parties often coordinate voters by limiting the size of the party slate, or by using complexvote managementschemes where voters are asked to randomize which candidate(s) they support.

These systems are notable for the absence of an orderedelectoral list.Candidates may coordinate their campaigns, and present or be presented as agents of a party, but voters may choose to support one candidate among the said group but not the others (that is,panachageis permitted).

Single transferable vote

edit

Many writers consider thesingle transferable voteto be a semi-proportional system because of its substantial favoritism towards major parties, generally caused by a combination of theDroop quotain small districts, as well as the substantial degree ofvote managementinvolved when there areexhausted ballots.[7]On the other hand, some authors describe it as a proportional system, on the grounds that it is theoreticallyweakly proportionalin the limit of infinitely-large constituencies.[8]However, it is worth noting that STV is only proportional forsolid coalitions,i.e. if voters rank candidates first by party and only then by candidate. As such, the proportionality of STV breaks down if voters aresplit across party linesor choose to support candidates of different parties.

A major complication with proportionality under STV is the need forconstituencies;small constituencies are strongly disproportional, but large constituencies make it difficult or impossible for voters to rank large numbers of candidates, turning the election into ade factoopen listPRsystem, particularly where voters lack any meaningful information about the candidates on their ballot.

The degree of proportionality of the results in a district (and when combined with other district results, the proportionality of results across a country) depends on the number of seats elected in the district. In the2011 Irish general election,Fine Gael received 45.2% of the seats with just 36.1% of the first preference votes. In the2020 Irish general election,theLabour Partyreceived 50% more votes than theSocial Democrats,but both parties won the same number of seats.Irelanduses districts of 3-7 members.

Similarly, the1998 Northern Ireland electionsresulted in theUlster Unionistswinning more seats than theSocial Democratic and Labour Partywith a smaller share of the vote.

The proportionality of STV can be controversial, especially in close elections like the 1981 election in Malta. In this election, theMaltese Labour partywon a majority of seats despite the Nationalist Party winning a majority offirst preferencevotes. This caused a constitutional crisis, leading to a provision to provide bonus seats in case of disproportional results. These bonus seats were needed in 1987, 1996, and 2008 to prevent furtherelectoral inversions.

The degree of proportionality nationwide is strongly related to the number of seats to be filled in each constituency. In a three-seat constituency using theDroop quota,a full quarter of the vote iswasted.In a nine-seat constituency, only a tenth of the vote iswasted,and a party needs only 10% of the vote to win a seat. Consequently, the best proportionality is achieved when there are a large number of representatives per constituency. TheHare quotais theoreticallyunbiased,allowing some of the errors in apportionment to cancel out if voters across the whole country. However, it also increases the vulnerability of STV tovote managementby large parties, allowing them to win the same number of seats they would have won under Droop.

Partisan systems

edit

Other forms of semi-proportional representation are based on, or at least use,party liststo work. Looking to the electoral systems effectively in use around the world, there are three general methods to reinforce themajoritarianprinciple of representation (but not necessarilymajoritarianismormajority rule,seeelectoral inversionandplurality) starting from basic PR mechanisms:parallel voting,the majority bonus system (MBS), and extremely reducedconstituencymagnitude.

Inadditional member systems(AMS), the number of additional members may not be sufficient to balance the disproportionality of the original system, thereby producing less than proportional results. When this imbalance is created intentionally, the result could be described as a semi-proportional system — for example, in theNational Assembly for Wales,where only 33.3% of members are compensatory. The electoral system commonly referred to in Britain as the "additional member system" is also used for theScottish Parliamentand theLondon Assembly,with generally proportional results. Similarly, in vote transfer basedmixed single votesystems, the number of compensatory seats may be too low (or too high) to achieve proportionality.[9]Such a system is used in Hungary in local elections.[10]The "scorporo"system used for theParliament of Italyfrom 1993 to 2005 and the electoral system for theNational Assembly of Hungarysince 1990 are also special cases, based on parallel voting, but also including compensatory mechanisms – which however are insufficient for providing proportional results.

Amajority bonus systemtakes an otherwise proportional system based on multi-member constituencies, and introduces disproportionality by granting additional seats to the first party or alliance. Majority bonuses help producelandslide victoriessimilar to those which occur in elections underplurality systems.Themajority bonussystem was first introduced byBenito Mussolinito win theelection of 1924.It has remained in use inItaly,as well as seeing some use inSan Marino,Greece,andFrance.[citation needed]

The simplest mechanism to reinforce major parties in PR system is to severely restrict the number of seats perelectoral district,which increases theDroop quota(the number of votes needed to be guaranteed a seat).

The last main group usually considered semi-proportional consists ofparallel votingmodels. The system used for theChamber of Deputies of Mexicosince 1996 is considered a parallel voting system, modified by a list-seat ceiling (8%) for over-representation of parties.

Usage

edit
Country Legislative body Latest election (year) Type of majoritarian system (Seats per

constituency)

Electoral system Total seats Governmental system Notes
Andorra General Council 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 2 (local districts) / 14 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting /superposition(MMM):

Party block voting(PBV) locally +list PRnationwide

28 Parliamentary system
Democratic Republic of the Congo National Assembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1–17 Coexistencemixed majoritarian (MMM):

First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts andList PRin multi-member districts (Largest remainder)

500
Djibouti National Assembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 3–28 Fusion/ majority jackpot (MBS):

80% of seats (rounded to the nearest integer) in each constituency are awarded to the party receiving the most votes (party block voting), remaining seats are allocated proportionally to other parties receiving over 10% (closed list,D'Hondt method)

65 Presidential system
France French PolynesiaAssembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 4–17 Two-roundmajority bonus system(MBS) in multi-member constituencies 57
Georgia Parliament 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts),

120 (national constituency)

Parallel voting /superposition(MMM):

Party-list PR(closed list) +First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP)

150 Parliamentary system
Greece Mixed-member majoritarian Majority bonus system (MBS)
Guinea National Assembly 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts),

76 (national constituency)

Parallel voting /superposition(MMM):

Party-list PR(Hare quota) +First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP)

114
Hungary National Assembly(Országgyűlés) 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 93 (national constituency) Supermixed/ Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM):

First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) + national list-PR for 93 seats (combination ofparallel votingandpositive vote transfer)

199 Parliamentary system Before the 2014, a different mixed system was used with a two-round system in single-member districts
Iraq Single non-transferable vote(SNTV)
Italy Chamber of Deputies 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 12 (Italians abroad constituency),?-? (multi-member districts)[citation needed] Superposition/ Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) using a single vote

List PR+First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP)

630 Parliamentary system
Senate 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 6 (Italians abroad constituency),?-? (multi-member districts)[citation needed] Superposition/ Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) using a single vote

List PR+First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP)

315 Parliamentary system
Republic of Korea(South Korea) National Assembly 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 17 supplementary seats (parallel voting), 30 additional seats (AMS), Supermixed/ Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM):

First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) andList PR(hybrid ofparallel votingandAMS)

300 Presidential system
Kuwait Single non-transferable vote(SNTV)
Kyrgyzstan Supreme Council 2021 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 54 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting /superposition(MMM):

Party-list PR(open list) +First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP)

90 Presidential system
Lithuania Seimas 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 70 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting /superposition(MMM):

Two-round system(TRS) for 71 seats +List PR(Largest remainder) for 70 seats

141 Semi-presidential system
Madagascar National Assembly 2019 Mixed-member majoritarian 1–2 Coexistence:First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) in 87 single-member districts,party-list PR(Closed list,highest averages method) in 32 two-member districts (64 seats inbinomial system) 151 Semi-presidential system
Mauritania National Assembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1–3 (local districts), 40 (nationwide constituency) Coexistence+superposition(parallel)supermixed/hybrid:

Two-round system(TRS) in single-member districts,two-round block voting(BV) in dual-member districts, andList PR(simple quota largest remainder; closed-list) in larger districts + twice 20 nationallyList PR(one set of 20 reserved for women)

157 Semi-presidential system
Monaco National Council 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 24 (nationwide constituency) Superposition/ Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM) using a single (panachage) ballot:

Plurality block voting(BV) in single nationwide constituency for 16 seats;D'Hondt method(8 seats)

24 Parliamentary system[citation needed]
Palestine Legislative Council 2006 Mixed-member majoritarian 1–9 (local districts), 66 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting /superposition(MMM):

First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts andPlurality block voting(BV) in two-seat districts for 66 seats in total (some reserved for Christians) +List PRfor 66 seats

132 Semi-presidential system In the 1996 elections, 88 PLC members were chosen from several multi-member constituencies viablock voting
Panama National Assembly 2019 Mixed-member majoritarian Coexistencemixed majoritarian (MMM):

First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts, Saripolo or Sartori method (Largest remainder,but remainders only for those with no seats) in multi-member districts

71 Presidential system
Philippines House of Representatives 2019 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts), 61 (nationwide constituency) Parallel voting /superposition(MMM):

First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) in single-member districts (243 in 2019) +List PR(closed lists;modifiedHare quotawith 3-seat cap and no remainders) (61 in 2019)

304 Presidential system
Russian Federation State Duma 2021 Mixed-member majoritarian [citation needed] Parallel voting /superposition(MMM):

First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) andList PR

450 Semi-presidential system
San Marino Majority bonus system (MBS) Parliamentary system
Scotland Parliament 2021 Mixed-member majoritarian 73 (constituency), 56 (7 list MSPs elected in each of the 8 regions) Additional Member System(AMS) 129 Parliamentary system
Senegal 2017 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 165 Presidential system
Seychelles 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 35 Presidential system
Singapore 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) andparty block voting(PBV) 104 (93 directly elected)
Sudan 2015 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 450
Switzerland Council of States

Only in:

  • names of cantons
2 Single non-transferable vote(SNTV) 46
Taiwan 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 113
Tajikistan 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 63
Thailand 2019 (usingMMP) Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel 500 The next election is scheduled to be held under parallel voting again, after one election (2019) held using a single vote MMP system
British Overseas Territories(United Kingdom) Gibraltar Limited voting(LV)
Pitcairn Islands Single non-transferable vote(SNTV)
Vanuatu Single non-transferable vote(SNTV)
Venezuela National Assembly 2020 Mixed-member majoritarian Parallel voting (MMM):

First-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) andlist PR

280 (277 directly elected) Presidential system
Zimbabwe National Assembly 2018 Mixed-member majoritarian 1 (local districts),

10 (proportional constituencies)

Mixed-member majoritarian (MMM):

210 seats byfirst-past-the-post(FPTP/SMP) in local districts

60 seats reserved for women bylist PR

270 Presidential system Voters cast a single vote

References

edit
  1. ^Douglas J. Amy."Semiproportional voting systems".Retrieved19 June2011.
  2. ^Giovanni Sartori(2005).Parties and Party Systems. A framework for analysis.European Consortium for Political Research.ISBN9780954796617.
  3. ^Douglas J. Amy (2000).Behind the Ballot Box: A Citizen's Guide to Voting Systems.Greenwood Publishing Group.ISBN9780275965860.
  4. ^P. Kestelman (June 2005)."Apportionment and Proportionality: A Measured View"(PDF).Retrieved19 June2011.
  5. ^Barry R. Weingast; Donald A. Wittman (19 October 2006).The Oxford handbook of political economy.Oxford University Press. pp. 105–.ISBN978-0-19-927222-8.Retrieved19 June2011.
  6. ^"Semi-Proportional Electoral Methods".Retrieved19 June2011.
  7. ^Norris, Pippa (1997)."Choosing Electoral Systems: Proportional, Majoritarian and Mixed Systems"(PDF).Harvard University.
  8. ^David M. Farrell Electoral Systems (2011)
  9. ^Golosov, G. V. (2013). "The Case for Mixed Single Vote Electoral Systems".The Journal of Social, Political, and Economic Studies.
  10. ^"2010. évi L. törvény a helyi önkormányzati képviselők és polgármesterek választásáról"[Act L. of 2010. on the election of local government representatives and mayors] (in Hungarian).