Ineconomics,atransaction costis acostincurred when making an economictradewhen participating in amarket.[1]
The idea that transactions form the basis of economic thinking was introduced by theinstitutional economistJohn R. Commonsin 1931.Oliver E. Williamson'sTransaction Cost Economicsarticle, published in 2008,[2]popularized the concept of transaction costs.[3]Douglass C. Northargues thatinstitutions,understood as the set of rules in a society, are key in the determination oftransactioncosts. In this sense, institutions that facilitate low transaction costs can boosteconomic growth.[4]
Alongsideproduction costs,transaction costs are one of the most significant factors in business operation and management.[5]
Definition
editWilliamson defines transaction costs as a cost innate in running an economic system of companies, comprising the total costs of making a transaction, including the cost of planning, deciding, changing plans, resolving disputes, and after-sales.[6]According to Williamson, the determinants of transaction costs are frequency,specificity,uncertainty, limited rationality, and opportunistic behavior.
Douglass North states that there are four factors that comprise transaction costs – "measurement", "enforcement", "ideological attitudes and perceptions", and "the size of the market".[4]Measurementrefers to the calculation of the value of all aspects of the good or service involved in the transaction.[4]Enforcementcan be defined as the need for an unbiased third party to ensure that neither party involved in the transaction reneges on their part of the deal.[4]These first two factors appear in the concept ofideological attitudes and perceptions,North's third aspect of transaction costs.[4]Ideological attitudes and perceptions encapsulate each individual's set of values, which influences their interpretation of the world.[4]The final aspect of transaction costs, according to North, ismarket size,which affects the partiality or impartiality of transactions.[4]
Dahlman categorized the content of transaction activities into three broad categories:[7][8]
- Search and information costsare costs such as in determining that the required good is available on the market, which has the lowest price, etc.
- Bargaining and decision costsare the costs required to come to an acceptable agreement with the other party to the transaction, drawing up an appropriatecontractand so on. Ingame theorythis is analyzed for instance in thegame of chicken.On asset markets and inorganizational economics,the transaction cost is some function of the distance between thesupply and demand.
- Policing and enforcement costsare the costs of making sure the other party sticks to the terms of the contract, and taking appropriate action, often through thelegal system,if this turns out not to be the case.
Steven N. S. Cheungdefines transaction costs as any costs that are not conceivable in a "Robinson Crusoeeconomy "—in other words, any costs that arise due to the existence ofinstitutions.For Cheung, term "transaction costs" are better described as "institutional costs".[9][10]Many economists, however, restrict this definition to exclude costs internal to an organization.[11]
History
editThe idea that transactions form the basis of an economic theory was introduced by theinstitutional economistJohn R. Commonsin 1931. He said that:
These individual actions are really trans-actions instead of either individual behavior or the "exchange" of commodities. It is this shift from commodities and individuals to transactions and working rules of collective action that marks the transition from the classical and hedonic schools to the institutional schools of economic thinking. The shift is a change in the ultimate unit of economic investigation. The classic and hedonic economists, with their communistic and anarchistic offshoots, founded their theories on the relation of man to nature, but institutionalism is a relation of man to man. The smallest unit of the classic economists was a commodity produced by labor. The smallest unit of the hedonic economists was the same or similar commodity enjoyed by ultimate consumers. One was the objective side, the other the subjective side, of the same relation between the individual and the forces of nature. The outcome, in either case, was the materialistic metaphor of an automatic equilibrium, analogous to the waves of the ocean, but personified as "seeking their level". But the smallest unit of the institutional economists is a unit of activity – a transaction, with its participants. Transactions intervene between the labor of the classic economists and the pleasures of the hedonic economists, simply because it is society that controls access to the forces of nature, and transactions are, not the "exchange of commodities", but the alienation and acquisition, between individuals, of the rights of property and liberty created by society, which must therefore be negotiated between the parties concerned before labor can produce, or consumers can consume, or commodities be physically exchanged ".
— John R. Commons,Institutional Economics,American Economic Review, Vol.21, pp.648-657, 1931
The term "transaction cost" is frequently and mistakenly thought to have been coined byRonald Coase,who used it to develop a theoretical framework for predicting when certain economic tasks would be performed byfirms,and when they would be performed on themarket.While he did not coin the specific term, Coase indeed discussed "costs of using the price mechanism" in his 1937 paperThe Nature of the Firm,where he first discusses the concept of transaction costs, marking the first time that the concept of transaction costs was introduced into the study of enterprises and market organizations. The term "Transaction Costs" itself can be traced back to the monetary economics literature of the 1950s, and does not appear to have been consciously 'coined' by any particular individual.[12]
Transaction cost as a formal theory started in the late 1960s and early 1970s.[13]And refers to the "Costs of Market Transactions" in his seminal work,The Problem of Social Cost(1960).
Arguably, transaction cost reasoning became most widely known throughOliver E. Williamson'sTransaction Cost Economics.Today, transaction cost economics is used to explain a number of different behaviours. Often this involves considering as "transactions" not only the obvious cases ofbuyingandselling,but also day-to-day emotional interactions and informalgiftexchanges. Williamson was one of the most cited social scientists at the turn of the century,[3]and was later awarded the 2009Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics.[14]
Technologies associated with theFourth Industrial Revolutionsuch as distributed ledger technology[15]and blockchains may reduce transaction costs when compared to traditional forms of contracting.
Examples
editA supplier may bid in a very competitive environment with a customer to build awidget.To make the widget, the supplier needs to build specialized machinery that cannot be used to make other products. Once the contract is awarded to the supplier, the relationship between customer and supplier changes from a competitive environment to amonopoly/monopsonyrelationship, known as abilateral monopoly.This means that the customer has greater leverage over the supplier. To avoid these potential costs, "hostages" may be swapped, which may involve partial ownership in the widget factory and revenue sharing.
Car companies and their suppliers often fit into this category, with the car companies forcing price cuts on their suppliers. Defense suppliers and the military appear to have the opposite problem, with cost overruns occurring quite often.
An example of measurement, one of North's four factors of transaction costs, occurs when roving bandits calculate the success of their banditry based on how much money they can take from their citizens.[16]Enforcement, the second of North's factors of transaction costs, may take the form of a mediator in dealings with the Sicilian mafia when it is not certain that both parties will maintain their end of the deal.[17]
Differences from neoclassical microeconomics
editWilliamson argues inThe Mechanisms of Governance(1996) that Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) differs fromneoclassical microeconomicsin the following points:
Item | Neoclassical microeconomics | Transaction cost economics |
---|---|---|
Behavioural assumptions[18] | Assumeshyperrationalityand ignores most of the hazards related to opportunism | Assumesbounded rationality |
Unit of analysis | Concerned with composite goods and services | Analyzes the transaction itself |
Governance structure | Describes the firm as aproduction function(a technological construction) | Describes the firm as a governance structure (an organizational construction) |
Problematic property rights and contracts | Often assumes that property rights are clearly defined and that the cost of enforcing those rights by the means of courts is negligible | Treats property rights and contracts as problematic |
Discrete structural analysis | Uses continuous marginal modes of analysis in order to achieve second-order economizing (adjusting margins) | Analyzes the basic structures of the firm and its governance in order to achieve first-order economizing (improving the basic governance structure) |
Remediableness | Recognizesprofit maximizationorcost minimizationas criteria of efficiency | Argues that there is no optimal solution and that all alternatives are flawed, thus bounding "optimal"efficiencyto the solution with no superior alternative and whose implementation produces net gains |
Imperfect Markets | Downplays the importance of imperfect markets | Robert AlmgrenandNeil Chriss,and laterRobert AlmgrenandTianhui Li,showed that the effects of transaction costs lead portfolio managers and options traders to deviate from neoclassically optimal portfolios extending the original analysis to derivative markets.[19][20] |
The transaction costs frameworks reject the notion ofinstrumental rationalityand its implications for predicting behavior. Whereas instrumental rationality assumes that an actor's understanding of the world is the same as the objective reality of the world, scholars who focus on transaction costs note that actors lack perfect information about the world (due to bounded rationality).[21]
Game theory
editIn game theory, transaction costs have been studied by Anderlini and Felli (2006).[22]They consider a model with two parties who together can generate a surplus. Both parties are needed to create the surplus. Yet, before the parties can negotiate about dividing the surplus, each party must incur transaction costs. Anderlini and Felli find that transaction costs cause a severe problem when there is a mismatch between the parties'bargaining powersand the magnitude of the transaction costs. In particular, if a party has large transaction costs but in future negotiations it can seize only a small fraction of the surplus (i.e., its bargaining power is small), then this party will not incur the transaction costs and hence the total surplus will be lost. It has been shown that the presence of transaction costs as modelled by Anderlini and Felli can overturn central insights of the Grossman-Hart-Mooretheory of the firm.[23][24]
Evaluative mechanisms
editOliver E. Williamson's[25]theory of evaluative mechanisms assess economic entitles based on eight variables: bounded rationality, atmosphere, small numbers, information asymmetric, frequency of exchange, asset specificity, uncertainty, and threat of opportunism.[26]
- Bounded Rationality: refers to the physical and mental, intellectual, emotional and other restrictions imposed by people participating in the transaction in order to maximize their interests.
- Atmosphere: The reason for increasing the difficulty of the transaction here is mostly because both parties to the transaction remain suspicious of the transaction, and the two sides are hostile to each other. Such a relationship cannot achieve a harmonious atmosphere, let alone a harmonious transaction relationship. This will cause both parties to increase security measures and increase expenditure during the transaction process.
- Small Numbers: Because the number of the two parties is not equal, the number of available transaction objects is reduced, and the market will be dominated by a few people, which leads to higher market expenditures. The main reason here is that some deals are too proprietary.
- Information Asymmetric: The pioneers in the market will control the direction of the market, and will know the information that is more beneficial to their own development earlier, and often these information will make opportunists and uncertain environments finalized, which will form a unique information gap. so as to form a transaction and obtain a profit
- Frequency of exchange: Frequency of exchange refers to buyer activity in the market or the frequency of transactions between the parties occurs. The higher the frequency of transactions, the higher the relative administrative and bargaining costs.
- Asset specificity: Asset specificity consist of site, physical asset, and human asset specificity. The asset specific investment is a specialized investment, which does not have market liquidity. Once the contract is terminated, the asset specific investment cannot to be redeployed. Therefore, a change or termination of this transaction will result in significant loss.[27]
- Uncertainty: Uncertainty refers to the risks that may occur in a market exchange. The increase of environmental uncertainty will be accompanied by the increase of transaction cost, such as information acquisition cost, supervision cost and bargaining cost.
- Threat of opportunism: Threat of opportunism is attributed to human nature. Opportunistic behavior of vendors can lead to higher transaction coordination costs or even termination of contracts. A company can use governance mechanism to reducing the threat of opportunism.
See also
editNotes
edit- ^Buy-side Use TCA to Measure Execution Performance,FIXGlobal, June 2010
- ^Williamson, O. E.,Outsourcing, Transaction Cost Economics and Supply Chain Management,Journal of Supply Chain Management,Volume 44, 2 Apr 2008, pages 2-82, accessed 14 February 2023
- ^abPessali, Huascar F. (2006). "The rhetoric of Oliver Williamson's transaction cost economics".Journal of Institutional Economics.2(1): 45–65.doi:10.1017/s1744137405000238.ISSN1744-1382.S2CID59432864.
- ^abcdefgNorth, Douglass C. 1992. "Transaction costs, institutions, and economic performance", San Francisco, CA: ICS Press.
- ^Young, Suzanne (2013)."Transaction Cost Economics".Encyclopedia of Corporate Social Responsibility.Springer Link. pp. 2547–2552.doi:10.1007/978-3-642-28036-8_221.ISBN978-3-642-28035-1.Retrieved2020-11-01.
- ^Downey, Lucas."Transaction Costs".investopedia.Retrieved21 May2022.
- ^Dahlman, Carl J. (1979). "The Problem of Externality".Journal of Law and Economics.22(1): 141–162.doi:10.1086/466936.ISSN0022-2186.S2CID154906153.
These, then, represent the first approximation to a workable concept of transaction costs: search and information costs, bargaining and decision costs, policing and enforcement costs.
- ^"Property rights, transaction costs, and institutions",The Open Field System and Beyond,Cambridge University Press, pp. 65–92, 1980-05-15,doi:10.1017/cbo9780511896392.004,ISBN9780521228817,retrieved2023-04-23
- ^Steven N. S. Cheung "On the New Institutional Economics",Contract Economics
- ^L. Werin and H. Wijkander (eds.), Basil Blackwell, 1992, pp. 48-65
- ^Harold Demsetz(2003) “Ownership and the Externality Problem.” In T. L. Anderson and F. S. McChesney (eds.) Property Rights: Cooperation, Conflict, and Law. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
- ^Robert KissellandMorton Glantz,Optimal Trading Strategies,AMACOM, 2003, pp. 1-23.
- ^Ketokivi, Mikko; Mahoney, Joseph T. (2017)."Transaction Cost Economics as a Theory of the Firm, Management, and Governance".Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Business and Management.doi:10.1093/acrefore/9780190224851.013.6.ISBN9780190224851.Retrieved2020-11-01.
- ^Special Issue of Journal of Retailing in Honor of The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2009 to Oliver E. Williamson, Volume 86, Issue 3, Pages 209-290 (September 2010). Edited byArne NygaardandRobert Dahlstrom
- ^Roeck, Dominik; Sternberg, Henrik; Hofmann, Erik (2019)."Distributed ledger technology in supply chains: a transaction cost perspective".International Journal of Production Research.58(7): 2124–2141.doi:10.1080/00207543.2019.1657247.ISSN0020-7543.
- ^Olson, Mancur (September 1993). "Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development".The American Political Science Review.87(3): 567–576.doi:10.2307/2938736.JSTOR2938736.S2CID145312307.
- ^Gambetta, Diego (1996).The Sicilian Mafia: the Business of Private Protection.Harvard University Press. p. 15.ISBN978-0674807426.
- ^Pessali, Huascar F. (2009-09-01). "Metaphors of Transaction Cost Economics".Review of Social Economy.67(3): 313–328.CiteSeerX10.1.1.322.614.doi:10.1080/00346760801933393.ISSN0034-6764.S2CID18240827.
- ^R.Almgren and N.Chriss, "Optimal execution of portfolio transactions" J. Risk, 3 (Winter 2000/2001) pp.5–39
- ^Robert Almgren;Tianhui Li(2016). "Option Hedging with Smooth Market Impact".Market Microstructure and Liquidity.2:1650002.doi:10.1142/S2382626616500027.
- ^North, Douglass C. (1990-10-01)."A Transaction Cost Theory of Politics".Journal of Theoretical Politics.2(4): 355–367.doi:10.1177/0951692890002004001.ISSN0951-6298.S2CID154451243.
- ^Anderlini, Luca; Felli, Leonardo (2006)."Transaction Costs and the Robustness of the Coase Theorem*"(PDF).The Economic Journal.116(508): 223–245.doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2006.01054.x.ISSN1468-0297.S2CID3059129.
- ^Müller, Daniel; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2016)."Transaction costs and the property rights approach to the theory of the firm".European Economic Review.87:92–107.doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2016.04.013.
- ^Schmitz, Patrick W. (2016)."The negotiators who knew too much: Transaction costs and incomplete information".Economics Letters.145:33–37.doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2016.05.009.
- ^Williamson, Oliver E. (1979)."Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations".The Journal of Law and Economics.22(2): 233–261.doi:10.1086/466942.ISSN0022-2186.S2CID8559551.
- ^Young, Suzanne (2013),"Transaction Cost Economics",in Idowu, Samuel O.; Capaldi, Nicholas; Zu, Liangrong; Gupta, Ananda Das (eds.),Encyclopedia of Corporate Social Responsibility,Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 2547–2552,doi:10.1007/978-3-642-28036-8_221,ISBN978-3-642-28036-8,retrieved2020-11-01
- ^Coggan, Anthea; van Grieken, Martijn; Jardi, Xavier; Boullier, Alexis (2017)."Does asset specificity influence transaction costs and adoption? An analysis of sugarcane farmers in the Great Barrier Reef catchments".Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy.6(1): 36–50.doi:10.1080/21606544.2016.1175975.ISSN2160-6544.S2CID168172769.
References
edit- North, Douglass C.1992. “Transaction costs, institutions, and economic performance.” San Francisco, CA: ICS Press.
- Cheung, Steven N. S. (1987). "Economic organization and transaction costs" (Document). TheNew Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economicsv. 2. pp. 55–58.
- Coggan, Anthea; van Grieken, Martijn; Jardi, Xavier; Boullier, Alexis (2017). "Does asset specificity influence transaction costs and adoption? An analysis of sugarcane farmers in the Great Barrier Reef catchments".Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy.6(1): 36–50.doi:10.1080/21606544.2016.1175975.ISSN2160-6544.
- Commons, J.R(1931)."Institutional Economics".American Economic Review.21:648–657.RetrievedFebruary 8,2013.
- Douma, Sytse;Schreuder, Hein(2012).Economic Approaches to Organizations(5th ed.). London: Pearson.ISBN9780273735298.
- Ketokivi, Mikko; Mahoney, Joseph T. (2017-10-26). "Transaction Cost Economics as a Theory of the Firm, Management, and Governance".Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Business and Management.doi:10.1093/acrefore/9780190224851.013.6. Retrieved 2020-11-01.
- Klaes, M. (2008). "transaction costs, history of,"The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics,2nd Edition.Abstract.
- Niehans, Jürg (1987). “Transaction costs,"The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics,v. 4, pp. 677–80.
- Pierre Schlag,The Problem of Transaction Costs,62 Southern California Law Review 1661 (1989).
- Coase, Ronald(1937)."The Nature of the Firm".Economica.4(16): 386–405.doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x.
- Coase, Ronald (1960)."The Problem of Social Cost".Journal of Law and Economics.3:1–44.doi:10.1086/466560.S2CID222331226.
- Williamson, Oliver E.(1981). "The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach,"The American Journal of Sociology,87(3), pp.548-577.
- _____ (1985).The Economic Institutions of Capitalism:Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting.Preview to p. 25.Archived2016-03-03 at theWayback MachineNew York, NY: Free Press.
- _____ (1996).The Mechanisms of Governance.Preview.Oxford University Press.
- _____ (2002). "The Theory of the Firm as Governance Structure: From Choice to Contract,"Journal of Economic Perspectives,16(3), pp.171-195.
- Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts, "Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs, and the Organization of Economic Activity," in J.E. Alt and K.A. Shepsle (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, Cambridge: University of Cambridge, 1990, 57-89.
- Milgrom, P.; Roberts, J. (1992).Economics, Organization and Management.Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.ISBN978-0-13-224650-7.
- Young, Suzanne (2013). "Transaction Cost Economics".Springer Link.doi:10.1007/978-3-642-28036-8_221. Retrieved 2020-11-01.