Uneconomic growthiseconomic growththat reflects or creates a decline in thequality of life.[1]The concept is used inhuman development theory,welfare theory,andecological economics.It is usually attributed to ecological economistHerman Daly,though other theorists may also be credited for the incipient idea,[2][3]According to Daly, "uneconomic growth occurs when increases in production come at an expense in resources and well-being that is worth more than the items made."[4]The cost, or decline in well-being, associated with extended economic growth is argued to arise as a result of "the social and environmental sacrifices made necessary by that growing encroachment on the eco-system."[5][6]
Types of growth
editThe rate or type of economic growth may have important consequences for the environment (theclimateandnatural capitalof ecologies). Concerns about possible negative effects of growth on the environment and society have led some to advocate lower levels of growth, from which comes the idea of uneconomic growth andGreen partieswhich argue that economies are part of a global society and a global ecology and cannot outstrip their natural growth without damaging them.
CanadianscientistDavid Suzukiargued in the 1990s that ecologies can only sustain typically about 1.5–3% new growth per year, and thus any requirement for greater returns fromagricultureorforestrywill necessarily cannibalize thenatural capitalofsoilorforest.Some think this argument can be applied even to more developed economies.
The role of technology, and Jevons paradox
editMainstream economists would argue that economies are driven by new technology—for instance, we have faster computers today than a year ago, but not necessarily physically more computers[citation needed].Growth that relies entirely on exploiting increased knowledge rather than exploiting increasedresource consumptionmay thus not qualify as uneconomic growth. In some cases, this may be true where technology enables lower amounts of input to be used in producing the same unit of product (and/or it reduces the amount or hazardousness of the waste generated per unit product produced) (e.g., the increased availability of movies through the Internet or cable television electronically may reduce the demand for physical video tapes or DVDs for films). Nonetheless, it is crucial to also recognise that innovation- or knowledge-driven growth still may not entirely resolve the problem of scale, or increasing resource consumption. For instance, there might likely be more computers due to greater demand and replacements for slower computers.
TheJevons Paradoxis the proposition that technological progress that increases the efficiency with which a resource is used, tends to increase (rather than decrease) the rate of consumption of that resource.[7][8]For example, given that expenditure on necessities and taxes remain the same, (i) the availability of energy-saving lightbulbs may mean lower electricity usage and fees for a household but this frees up more discretionary, disposable income for additional consumption elsewhere (an example of the"rebound effect")[9][10]and (ii) technology (or globalisation) that leads to the availability of cheaper goods for consumers also frees up discretionary income for increased consumptive spending.
On the other hand, new renewable energy andclimate change mitigationtechnology (such as artificial photosynthesis) has been argued to promote a prolonged era of human stewardship over ecosystems known as theSustainocene.In the Sustainocene, "instead of the cargo-cult ideology of perpetual economic growth through corporate pillage of nature, globalised artificial photosynthesis will facilitate asteady state economyand further technological revolutions such as domestic nano-factories and e-democratic input to local communal and global governance structures. In such a world, humans will no longer feel economically threatened, but rather proud, that their moral growth has allowed them to upholdRights of Nature."[11]
See also
editReferences
edit- ^Orr, C.J. (2018). "Uneconomic Growth".Encyclopedia of the Anthropocene:277–285.doi:10.1016/B978-0-12-809665-9.10474-4.
- ^Daly, H. 2007. Ecological economics: the concept of scale and its relation to allocation, distribution, and uneconomic growth. pp. 82–103 in H. Daly.Ecological Economics and Sustainable Development: Selected Essays of Herman Daly.Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
- ^Daly, H. 1999. Uneconomic growth and the built environment: in theory and in fact. In C.J. Kibert (ed.).Reshaping the Built Environment: Ecology, Ethics, and Economics.Washington DC: Island Press.
- ^Daly, H. 2005. Economics in a full world.Scientific American293(3): 100–107.
- ^Daly, H. (26 April 1999)."Uneconomic growth in theory and in fact. The First Annual Feasta Lecture".Feasta Review.Trinity College, Dublin.Retrieved7 December2014.
- ^Daly, H. and Farley, J. 2004.Ecological Economics: Principles and Applications.Washington: Island Press.
- ^Jevons, W.S. 1865.The Coal Question: An Inquiry Concerning the Progress of the Nation, and the Probable Exhaustion of Our Coal-Mines.London: Macmillan and Co.
- ^Czech, B. 2006. If Rome is burning, why are we fiddling?Conservation Biology20 (6): 1563–1565.
- ^Binswanger, M. 2001. Technological progress and sustainable development: what about the rebound effect?Ecological Economics36(1): 119–132.
- ^Herring, H. 2000. Is energy efficiency environmentally friendly?Energy & Environment11(3): 313–325.
- ^Thomas Faunce.'Artificial Photosynthesis Could Extend Rights to Nature. The Conversation 2 July 2013.https://theconversation /artificial-photosynthesis-could-extend-rights-to-nature-15380(accessed 2 July 2013).
Further reading
edit- Baker, Linda (May–June 1999). "Real Wealth: The Genuine Progress Indicator Could Provide an Environmental Measure of the Planet's Health".E Magazine:37–41.
- Cobb, Clifford;Ted Halstead;Jonathan Rowe (October 1995). "If the GDP Is Up, Why Is America Down?".Atlantic Monthly:59–78.
- Takis Fotopoulos:"The Multidimensional Crisis andInclusive Democracy",Athens 2005. English online version:[1]
- Rowe, Jonathan; Judith Silverstein (March 1999). "TheGDPMyth: Why 'Growth' Isn't Always a Good Thing ".Washington Monthly:17–21.
- Rowe, Jonathan (July–August 1999). "The Growth Consensus Unravels".Dollars & Sense:15–18, 33.