Inflation
Part ofa serieson |
Macroeconomics |
---|
Ineconomics,inflationis a general increase in the prices of goods and services in aneconomy.This is usually measured using aconsumer price index(CPI).[3][4][5][6]When the general price level rises, each unit of currency buys fewer goods and services; consequently, inflation corresponds to a reduction in thepurchasing powerof money.[7][8]The opposite of CPI inflation isdeflation,a decrease in the general price level of goods and services. The common measure of inflation is theinflation rate,the annualized percentage change in a generalprice index.[9]As prices faced by households do not all increase at the same rate, theconsumer price index(CPI) is often used for this purpose.
Changes in inflation are widely attributed to fluctuations inrealdemandfor goods and services (also known asdemand shocks,including changes infiscalormonetary policy), changes in available supplies such as duringenergy crises(also known assupply shocks), or changes in inflation expectations, which may be self-fulfilling.[10]Moderate inflation affects economies in both positive and negative ways. The negative effects would include an increase in theopportunity costof holding money; uncertainty over future inflation, which may discourage investment and savings; and, if inflation were rapid enough, shortages ofgoodsas consumers beginhoardingout of concern that prices will increase in the future. Positive effects include reducing unemployment due tonominal wage rigidity,[11]allowing the central bank greater freedom in carrying outmonetary policy,encouraging loans and investment instead of money hoarding, and avoiding the inefficiencies associated with deflation.
Today, some economists favour a low and steady rate of inflation, though inflation is less popular with the general public than with economists, since "inflation simultaneously transfers some of [the] people’s income into the hands of government."[12]Low (as opposed to zero ornegative) inflation reduces the probability of economicrecessionsby enabling the labor market to adjust more quickly in a downturn and reduces the risk that aliquidity trappreventsmonetary policyfrom stabilizing the economy while avoiding the costs associated with high inflation.[13]The task of keeping the rate of inflation low and stable is usually given tocentral banksthat control monetary policy, normally through the setting of interest rates and by carrying outopen market operations.[10]
Terminology
[edit]The term originates from the Latininflare(to blow into or inflate). Conceptually, inflation refers to the general trend of prices, not changes in any specific price. For example, if people choose to buy more cucumbers than tomatoes, cucumbers consequently become more expensive and tomatoes less expensive. These changes are not related to inflation; they reflect a shift in tastes. Inflation is related to the value of currency itself. When currency was linked with gold, if new gold deposits were found, the price of gold and the value of currency would fall, and consequently, prices of all other goods would become higher.[14]
Classical economics
[edit]By the nineteenth century, economists categorised three separate factors that cause a rise or fall in the price of goods: a change in thevalueor production costs of the good, a change in theprice of moneywhich then was usually a fluctuation in thecommodityprice of the metallic content in the currency, andcurrency depreciationresulting from an increased supply of currency relative to the quantity of redeemable metal backing the currency. Following the proliferation of privatebanknotecurrency printed during theAmerican Civil War,the term "inflation" started to appear as a direct reference to thecurrency depreciationthat occurred as the quantity of redeemable banknotes outstripped the quantity of metal available for their redemption. At that time, the term inflation referred to thedevaluationof the currency, and not to a rise in the price of goods.[15]This relationship between the over-supply of banknotes and a resultingdepreciationin their value was noted by earlier classical economists such asDavid HumeandDavid Ricardo,who would go on to examine and debate what effect a currency devaluation has on the price of goods.[16]
Related concepts
[edit]Other economic concepts related to inflation include:deflation– a fall in the general price level;[17]disinflation– a decrease in the rate of inflation;[18]hyperinflation– an out-of-control inflationary spiral;[19]stagflation– a combination of inflation, slow economic growth and high unemployment;[20]reflation– an attempt to raise the general level of prices to counteract deflationary pressures;[21]andasset price inflation– a general rise in the prices of financial assets without a corresponding increase in the prices of goods or services;[22]agflation– an advanced increase in theprice for foodand industrial agricultural crops when compared with the general rise in prices.[23]
More specific forms of inflation refer to sectors whose prices vary semi-independently from the general trend. "House price inflation" applies to changes in thehouse price index[24]while "energy inflation" is dominated by the costs of oil and gas.[25]
History
[edit]Overview
[edit]Inflation has been a feature of history during the entire period when money has been used as a means of payment. One of the earliest documented inflations occurred inAlexander the Great's empire 330BCE.[26]Historically, whencommodity moneywas used, periods of inflation and deflation would alternate depending on the condition of the economy. However, when large, prolonged infusions of gold or silver into an economy occurred, this could lead to long periods of inflation.
The adoption offiat currencyby many countries, from the 18th century onwards, made much larger variations in the supply of money possible.[27]Rapid increases in themoney supplyhave taken place a number of times in countries experiencing political crises, producinghyperinflations– episodes of extreme inflation rates much higher than those observed in earlier periods ofcommodity money.Thehyperinflation in the Weimar Republicof Germany is a notable example. Thehyperinflationin Venezuela is the highest in the world, with an annual inflation rate of 833,997% as of October 2018.[28]
Historically, inflations of varying magnitudes have occurred, interspersed with corresponding deflationary periods,[26]from theprice revolutionof the 16th century, which was driven by the flood of gold and particularly silver seized and mined by the Spaniards in Latin America, to the largest paper money inflation of all time in Hungary after World War II.[29]
However, since the 1980s, inflation has been held low and stable in countries with independentcentral banks.This has led to a moderation of thebusiness cycleand a reduction in variation in most macroeconomic indicators – an event known as theGreat Moderation.[30]
Ancient Europe
[edit]Alexander the Great's conquest of thePersian Empirein 330 BCE was followed by one of the earliest documented inflation periods in the ancient world.[26]Rapid increases in the quantity of money or in the overallmoney supplyhave occurred in many different societies throughout history, changing with different forms of money used.[31][32]For instance, when silver was used as currency, the government could collect silver coins, melt them down, mix them with other, less valuable metals such as copper or lead and reissue them at the samenominal value,a process known asdebasement.At the ascent ofNeroas Roman emperor in AD 54, thedenariuscontained more than 90% silver, but by the 270s hardly any silver was left. By diluting the silver with other metals, the government could issue more coins without increasing the amount of silver used to make them. When the cost of each coin is lowered in this way, the government profits from an increase inseigniorage.[33]This practice would increase the money supply but at the same time the relative value of each coin would be lowered. As the relative value of the coins becomes lower, consumers would need to give more coins in exchange for the same goods and services as before. These goods and services would experience a price increase as the value of each coin is reduced.[34]Again at the end of the third century CE during the reign ofDiocletian,theRoman Empireexperienced rapid inflation.[26]
Ancient China
[edit]Song dynastyChina introduced the practice of printing paper money to createfiat currency.[35]During the MongolYuan dynasty,the government spent a great deal of money fightingcostly wars,and reacted by printing more money, leading to inflation.[36]Fearing the inflation that plagued the Yuan dynasty, theMing dynastyinitially rejected the use of paper money, and reverted to using copper coins.[37]
Medieval Egypt
[edit]During theMaliankingMansa Musa'shajjtoMeccain 1324, he was reportedly accompanied by acamel trainthat included thousands of people and nearly a hundred camels. When he passed throughCairo,he spent or gave away so much gold that it depressed its price in Egypt for over a decade,[38]reducing its purchasing power. A contemporary Arab historian remarked about Mansa Musa's visit:
Gold was at a high price in Egypt until they came in that year. Themithqaldid not go below 25dirhamsand was generally above, but from that time its value fell and it cheapened in price and has remained cheap till now. The mithqal does not exceed 22 dirhams or less. This has been the state of affairs for about twelve years until this day by reason of the large amount of gold which they brought into Egypt and spent there [...].
— Chihab Al-Umari,Kingdom of Mali[39]
Medieval age and "price revolution" in Western Europe
[edit]There is no reliable evidence of inflation in Europe for the thousand years that followed the fall of the Roman Empire, but from theMiddle Agesonwards reliable data do exist. Mostly, the medieval inflation episodes were modest, and there was a tendency that inflationary periods were followed by deflationary periods.[26]
From the second half of the 15th century to the first half of the 17th, Western Europe experienced a major inflationary cycle referred to as the "price revolution",[40][41]with prices on average rising perhaps sixfold over 150 years. This is often attributed to the influx of gold and silver from theNew WorldintoHabsburg Spain,[42]with wider availability ofsilverin previouslycash-starved Europecausing widespread inflation.[43][44]European population rebound from theBlack Deathbegan before the arrival of New World metal, and may have begun a process of inflation that New World silver compounded later in the 16th century.[45]
After 1700
[edit]A pattern of intermittent inflation and deflation periods persisted for centuries until theGreat Depressionin the 1930s, which was characterized by major deflation. Since the Great Depression, however, there has been a general tendency for prices to rise every year. In the 1970s and early 1980s, annual inflation in most industrialized countries reached two digits (ten percent or more). The double-digit inflation era was of short duration, however, inflation by the mid-1980s returned to more modest levels. Amid this, general trends there have been spectacular high-inflation episodes in individual countries ininterwar Europe,towards the end of theNationalist Chinese governmentin 1948–1949, and later in some Latin American countries, in Israel, and in Zimbabwe. Some of these episodes are consideredhyperinflationperiods, normally designating inflation rates that surpass 50 percent monthly.[26]
Measures
[edit]Given that there are many possible measures of the price level, there are many possible measures of price inflation. Most frequently, the term "inflation" refers to a rise in a broad price index representing the overall price level for goods and services in the economy. Theconsumer price index(CPI), thepersonal consumption expenditures price index(PCEPI) and theGDP deflatorare some examples of broad price indices. However, "inflation" may also be used to describe a rising price level within a narrower set of assets, goods or services within the economy, such ascommodities(including food, fuel, metals),tangible assets(such as real estate), services (such as entertainment and health care), orlabor.Although the values of capital assets are often casually said to "inflate," this should not be confused with inflation as a defined term; a more accurate description for an increase in the value of a capital asset is appreciation. The FBI (CCI), theproducer price index,andemployment cost index(ECI) are examples of narrow price indices used to measure price inflation in particular sectors of the economy.Core inflationis a measure of inflation for a subset of consumer prices that excludes food and energy prices, which rise and fall more than other prices in the short term. TheFederal Reserve Boardpays particular attention to the core inflation rate to get a better estimate of long-term future inflation trends overall.[47]
The inflation rate is most widely calculated by determining the movement or change in a price index, typically theconsumer price index.[48]
The inflation rate is the percentage change of a price index over time. TheRetail Prices Indexis also a measure of inflation that is commonly used in the United Kingdom. It is broader than the CPI and contains a larger basket of goods and services. Inflation is politically driven, and policy can directly influnce the trend of inflation.
The RPI is indicative of the experiences of a wide range of household types, particularly low-income households.[49]
To illustrate the method of calculation, in January 2007, the U.S. Consumer Price Index was 202.416, and in January 2008 it was 211.080. The formula for calculating the annual percentage rate inflation in the CPI over the course of the year is:
The resulting inflation rate for the CPI in this one-year period is 4.28%, meaning the general level of prices for typical U.S. consumers rose by approximately four percent in 2007.[50]
Other widely used price indices for calculating price inflation include the following:
- Producer price indices(PPIs) which measures average changes in prices received by domestic producers for their output. This differs from the CPI in that price subsidization, profits, and taxes may cause the amount received by the producer to differ from what the consumer paid. There is also typically a delay between an increase in the PPI and any eventual increase in the CPI. Producer price index measures the pressure being put on producers by the costs of their raw materials. This could be "passed on" to consumers, or it could be absorbed by profits, or offset by increasing productivity. In India and the United States, an earlier version of the PPI was called theWholesale price index.
- Commodity price indices,which measure the price of a selection of commodities. In the present commodity price indices are weighted by the relative importance of the components to the "all in" cost of an employee.
- Core price indices:because food and oil prices can change quickly due to changes insupply and demandconditions in the food and oil markets, it can be difficult to detect the long run trend in price levels when those prices are included. Therefore, moststatistical agenciesalso report a measure of 'core inflation', which removes the most volatile components (such as food and oil) from a broad price index like the CPI. Because core inflation is less affected by short run supply and demand conditions in specific markets,central banksrely on it to better measure the inflationary effect of currentmonetary policy.
Other common measures of inflation are:
- GDP deflatoris a measure of the price of all the goods and services included in gross domestic product (GDP). TheUS Commerce Departmentpublishes a deflator series for US GDP, defined as its nominal GDP measure divided by its real GDP measure.
∴
- Regional inflationThe Bureau of Labor Statistics breaks down CPI-U calculations down to different regions of the US.
- Historical inflationBefore collecting consistent econometric data became standard for governments, and for the purpose of comparing absolute, rather than relative standards of living, various economists have calculated imputed inflation figures. Most inflation data before the early 20th century is imputed based on the known costs of goods, rather than compiled at the time. It is also used to adjust for the differences in real standard of living for the presence of technology.
- Asset price inflationis an undue increase in the prices of real assets, such as real estate.
In some cases, the measures are meant to be more humorous or to reflect a single place. This includes:
- TheChristmas Price Index,which calculates the cost of the items mentioned in a song, "The Twelve Days of Christmas ".[51]
- TheBig Mac Index,which compares prices across countries.[52]
- TheJollof index,which calculates the price of food needed to make aJollof rice,a popular African dish.[53]
- TheTwo Dishes One Soup Index,which calculates the price of food needed to cook one soup and two other dishes for a small family in Hong Kong.
- TheHerengracht index,which calculates the price of housing in a fashionable neighborhood ofAmsterdam.[54]
- TheLipstick index,which claimed that when the economy got worse, small luxury sales, such aslipstick,would go up.[55]
Issues in measuring
[edit]Measuring inflation in an economy requires objective means of differentiating changes in nominal prices on a common set of goods and services, and distinguishing them from those price shifts resulting from changes in value such as volume, quality, or performance. For example, if the price of a can of corn changes from $0.90 to $1.00 over the course of a year, with no change in quality, then this price difference represents inflation. This single price change would not, however, represent general inflation in an overall economy. Overall inflation is measured as the price change of a large "basket" of representative goods and services. This is the purpose of aprice index,which is the combined price of a "basket" of many goods and services. The combined price is the sum of the weighted prices of items in the "basket". A weighted price is calculated by multiplying theunit priceof an item by the number of that item the average consumer purchases. Weighted pricing is necessary to measure the effect of individual unit price changes on the economy's overall inflation. Theconsumer price index,for example, uses data collected by surveying households to determine what proportion of the typical consumer's overall spending is spent on specific goods and services, and weights the average prices of those items accordingly. Those weighted average prices are combined to calculate the overall price. To better relate price changes over time, indexes typically choose a "base year" price and assign it a value of 100. Index prices in subsequent years are then expressed in relation to the base year price.[56]While comparing inflation measures for various periods one has to take into consideration thebase effectas well.
Inflation measures are often modified over time, either for the relative weight of goods in the basket, or in the way in which goods and services from the present are compared with goods and services from the past. Basket weights are updated regularly, usually every year, to adapt to changes in consumer behavior. Sudden changes in consumer behavior can still introduce a weighting bias in inflation measurement. For example, during the COVID-19 pandemic it has been shown that the basket of goods and services was no longer representative of consumption during the crisis, as numerous goods and services could no longer be consumed due to government containment measures ( "lock-downs" ).[57][58]
Over time, adjustments are also made to the type of goods and services selected to reflect changes in the sorts of goods and services purchased by 'typical consumers'. New products may be introduced, older products disappear, the quality of existing products may change, and consumer preferences can shift. Different segments of the population may naturally consume different "baskets" of goods and services and may even experience different inflation rates. It is argued that companies have put more innovation into bringing down prices for wealthy families than for poor families.[59]
Inflation numbers are oftenseasonally adjustedto differentiate expected cyclical cost shifts. For example, home heating costs are expected to rise in colder months, and seasonal adjustments are often used when measuring inflation to compensate for cyclical energy or fuel demand spikes. Inflation numbers may be averaged or otherwise subjected to statistical techniques to removestatistical noiseandvolatilityof individual prices.[60][61]
When looking at inflation, economic institutions may focus only on certain kinds of prices, orspecial indices,such as thecore inflationindex which is used by central banks to formulatemonetary policy.[62]
Most inflation indices are calculated from weighted averages of selected price changes. This necessarily introduces distortion, and can lead to legitimate disputes about what the true inflation rate is. This problem can be overcome by including all available price changes in the calculation, and then choosing themedianvalue.[63]In some other cases, governments may intentionally report false inflation rates; for instance, during the presidency ofCristina Kirchner(2007–2015) thegovernment of Argentinawas criticised for manipulating economic data, such as inflation and GDP figures, for political gain and to reduce payments on its inflation-indexed debt.[64][65]
Official vs. true vs. perceived inflation
[edit]The true inflation is one percentage point lower than the official one, according to research. Therefore, the 2% inflation target is needed to prevent the true inflation being close to zero or even deflation. The reasons are the following:[66]
- Substitution effect:People buy fewer products with the highest price rises and more of those whose prices have risen less. Therefore, the price of their non-fixed shopping basket rises less than that of a fixed shopping basket.
- Unobserved quality improvements:Even though statisticians try to take quality improvements into account, they are not able to do it fully. This is why people rather buy current products at the higher prices than old products at their old prices.
- New goods:The current shopping basket is much better, because it has goods that you previously could not even dream of.[67]
Nevertheless, people overestimate the inflation even vs. the measured inflation. This is because they focus more on commonly-bought items than on durable goods, and more on price increases than on price decreases.[68]
On the other hand, different people have different shopping baskets and hence face different inflation rates.[68]
Inflation expectations
[edit]Inflation expectations or expected inflation is the rate of inflation that is anticipated for some time in the foreseeable future. There are two major approaches to modeling the formation of inflation expectations.Adaptive expectationsmodels them as a weighted average of what was expected one period earlier and the actual rate of inflation that most recently occurred.Rational expectationsmodels them as unbiased, in the sense that the expected inflation rate is not systematically above or systematically below the inflation rate that actually occurs.
A long-standing survey of inflation expectations is the University of Michigan survey.[69]
Inflation expectations affect the economy in several ways. They are more or less built intonominal interest rates,so that a rise (or fall) in the expected inflation rate will typically result in a rise (or fall) in nominal interest rates, giving a smaller effect if any onreal interest rates.In addition, higher expected inflation tends to be built into the rate of wage increases, giving a smaller effect if any on the changes inreal wages.Moreover, the response of inflationary expectations to monetary policy can influence the division of the effects of policy between inflation and unemployment (seemonetary policy credibility).
Causes
[edit]This sectionmay be in need of reorganization to comply with Wikipedia'slayout guidelines.(February 2024) |
Historical approaches
[edit]Theories of the origin and causes of inflation have existed since at least the 16th century. Two competing theories, thequantity theory of moneyand thereal bills doctrine,appeared in various disguises during century-long debates on recommended central bank behaviour. In the 20th century,Keynesian,monetaristandnew classical(also known asrational expectations) views on inflation dominated post-World War IImacroeconomicsdiscussions, which were often heated intellectual debates, until some kind of synthesis of the various theories was reached by the end of the century.
Before 1936
[edit]Theprice revolutionfrom ca. 1550–1700 caused several thinkers to present what is now considered to be early formulations of thequantity theory of money(QTM). Other contemporary authors attributed rising price levels to the debasement of national coinages. Later research has shown that also growing output ofCentral Europeansilver mines and an increase in thevelocity of moneybecause of innovations in the payment technology, in particular the increased use ofbills of exchange,contributed to the price revolution.[70]
An alternative theory, thereal bills doctrine(RBD), originated in the 17th and 18th century, receiving its first authoritative exposition inAdam Smith'sThe Wealth of Nations.[71]It asserts that banks should issue their money in exchange for short-term real bills of adequate value. As long as banks only issue a dollar in exchange for assets worth at least a dollar, the issuing bank's assets will naturally move in step with its issuance of money, and the money will hold its value. Should the bank fail to get or maintain assets of adequate value, then the bank's money will lose value, just as any financial security will lose value if its asset backing diminishes. The real bills doctrine (also known as the backing theory) thus asserts that inflation results when money outruns its issuer's assets. The quantity theory of money, in contrast, claims that inflation results when money outruns the economy's production of goods.
During the 19th century, three different schools debated these questions: TheBritish Currency Schoolupheld a quantity theory view, believing that theBank of England's issues of bank notes should vary one-for-one with the bank's gold reserves. In contrast to this, theBritish Banking Schoolfollowed the real bills doctrine, recommending that the bank's operations should be governed by the needs of trade: Banks should be able to issue currency against bills of trading, i.e. "real bills" that they buy from merchants. A third group, the Free Banking School, held that competitive private banks would not overissue, even though a monopolist central bank could be believed to do it.[72]
The debate between currency, or quantity theory, and banking schools during the 19th century prefigures current questions about the credibility of money in the present. In the 19th century, the banking schools had greater influence in policy in the United States and Great Britain, while thecurrency schoolshad more influence "on the continent", that is in non-British countries, particularly in theLatin Monetary Unionand theScandinavian Monetary Union.
During the Bullionist Controversy during theNapoleonic Wars,David Ricardoargued that the Bank of England had engaged in over-issue of bank notes, leading to commodity price increases. In the late 19th century, supporters of the quantity theory of money led byIrving Fisherdebated with supporters ofbimetallism.Later,Knut Wicksellsought to explain price movements as the result of real shocks rather than movements in money supply, resounding statements from the real bills doctrine.[70]
In 2019, monetary historiansThomas M. HumphreyandRichard Timberlakepublished "Gold, the Real Bills Doctrine, and the Fed: Sources of Monetary Disorder 1922–1938".[73]
Keynes and the early Keynesians
[edit]John Maynard Keynes in his 1936 main workThe General Theory of Employment, Interest and Moneyemphasized that wages and prices werestickyin the short run, but gradually responded toaggregate demandshocks. These could arise from many different sources, e.g. autonomous movements in investment or fluctuations in private wealth or interest rates.[26]Economic policy could also affect demand,monetary policyby affecting interest rates andfiscal policyeither directly through the level ofgovernment final consumption expenditureor indirectly by changingdisposable incomevia tax changes.
The various sources of variations in aggregate demand will cause cycles in both output and price levels. Initially, a demand change will primarily affect output because of the price stickiness, but eventually prices and wages will adjust to reflect the change in demand. Consequently, movements in real output and prices will be positively, but not strongly, correlated.[26]
Keynes' propositions formed the basis ofKeynesian economicswhich came to dominate macroeconomic research and economic policy in the first decades after World War II.[10]: 526 Other Keynesian economists developed and reformed several of Keynes' ideas. Importantly,Alban William Phillipsin 1958 published indirect evidence of a negative relation between inflation and unemployment, confirming the Keynesian emphasis on a positive correlation between increases in real output (normally accompanied by a fall in unemployment) and rising prices, i.e. inflation. Phillips' findings were confirmed by other empirical analyses and became known as aPhillips curve.It quickly became central to macroeconomic thinking, apparently offering a stable trade-off betweenprice stabilityand employment. The curve was interpreted to imply that a country could achieve low unemployment if it were willing to tolerate a higher inflation rate or vice versa.[10]: 173
The Phillips curve model described the U.S. experience well in the 1960s, but failed to describe thestagflation experienced in the 1970s.
Monetarism
[edit]During the 1960s the Keynesian view of inflation and macroeconomic policy altogether were challenged bymonetaristtheories, led byMilton Friedman.[10]: 528–529 Friedman famously stated that"Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon."[74]He revived thequantity theory of moneybyIrving Fisherand others, making it into a central tenet of monetarist thinking, arguing that the most significant factor influencing inflation or deflation is how fast themoney supplygrows or shrinks.[75]
The quantity theory of money, simply stated, says that any change in the amount of money in a system will change the price level. This theory begins with theequation of exchange:
where
- is the nominal quantity of money;
- is thevelocity of moneyin final expenditures;
- is the general price level;
- is an index of thereal valueof final expenditures.
In this formula, the general price level is related to the level of real economic activity (Q), the quantity of money (M) and the velocity of money (V). The formula itself is simply an uncontroversialaccounting identitybecause the velocity of money (V) is defined residually from the equation to be the ratio of final nominal expenditure () to the quantity of money (M).[76]: 99
Monetarists assumed additionally that the velocity of money is unaffected by monetary policy (at least in the long run), that the real value of output is alsoexogenousin the long run, its long-run value being determined independently by the productive capacity of the economy, and that money supply is exogenous and can be controlled by the monetary authorities. Under these assumptions, the primary driver of the change in the general price level is changes in the quantity of money.[76]Consequently, monetarists contended that monetary policy, not fiscal policy, was the most potent instrument to influence aggregate demand, real output and eventually inflation. This was contrary to Keynesian thinking which in principle recognized a role for monetary policy, but in practice believed that the effect from interest rate changes to the real economy was slight, making monetary policy an ineffective instrument, preferring fiscal policy.[10]: 528 Conversely, monetarists considered fiscal policy, or government spending and taxation, as ineffective in controlling inflation.[75]
Friedman also took issue with the traditional Keynesian view concerning the Phillips curve. He, together withEdmund Phelps,contended that the trade-off between inflation and unemployment implied by the Phillips curve was only temporary, but not permanent. If politicians tried to exploit it, it would eventually disappear because higher inflation would over time be built into the economic expectations of households and firms.[10]: 528–529 This line of thinking led to the concept ofpotential output(sometimes called the "natural gross domestic product" ), a level of GDP where the economy is stable in the sense that inflation will neither decrease nor increase. This level may itself change over time when institutional or natural constraints change. It corresponds to the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment,NAIRU,or the "natural" rate of unemployment (sometimes called the "structural" level of unemployment).[10]If GDP exceeds its potential (and unemployment consequently is below the NAIRU), the theory says that inflation willaccelerateas suppliers increase their prices. If GDP falls below its potential level (and unemployment is above the NAIRU), inflation willdecelerateas suppliers attempt to fill excess capacity, cutting prices and undermining inflation.[77]
Rational expectations theory
[edit]In the early 1970s,rational expectations theoryled by economists likeRobert Lucas,Thomas SargentandRobert Barrotransformed macroeconomic thinking radically. They held that economic actors look rationally into the future when trying to maximize their well-being, and do not respond solely to immediateopportunity costsand pressures.[10]: 529–530 In this view, future expectations and strategies are important for inflation as well. One implication was that agents would anticipate the likely behaviour of central banks and base their own actions on these expectations. A central bank having a reputation of being "soft" on inflation will generate high inflation expectations, which again will be self-fulfilling when all agents build expectations of future high inflation into their nominal contracts like wage agreements. On the other hand, if the central bank has a reputation of being "tough" on inflation, then such a policy announcement will be believed and inflationary expectations will come down rapidly, thus allowing inflation itself to come down rapidly with minimal economic disruption. The implication is thatcredibilitybecomes very important for central banks in fighting inflation.[10]: 467–469
New Keynesians
[edit]Events during the 1970s proved Milton Friedman and other critics of the traditional Phillips curve right: The relation between the inflation rate and the unemployment rate broke down. Eventually, a consensus was established that the break-down was due to agents changing their inflation expectations, confirming Friedman's theory. As a consequence, the notion of anatural rate of unemployment(alternatively called the structural rate of unemployment) was accepted by most economists, meaning that there is a specific level of unemployment that is compatible with stable inflation.Stabilization policymust therefore try to steer economic activity so that the actual unemployment rate converges towards that level.[10]: 176–189 The trade-off between theunemployment rateand inflation implied by Phillips thus holds in the short term, but not in the long term.[78]Also theoil crises of the 1970scausing at the same time rising unemployment and rising inflation (i.e.stagflation) led to a broad recognition by economists thatsupply shockscould independently affect inflation.[26][10]: 529
During the 1980s a group of researchers namednew Keynesiansemerged who accepted many originally non-Keynesian concepts like the importance of monetary policy, the existence of a natural level of unemployment and the incorporation of rational expectations formation as a reasonable benchmark. At the same time they believed, like Keynes did, that variousmarket imperfectionsin different markets like labour markets and financial markets were also important to study to understand both inflation generation andbusiness cycles.[10]: 533–534 During the 1980s and 1990s, there were often heated intellectual debates between new Keynesians and new classicals, but by the 2000s, a synthesis gradually emerged. The result has been called thenew Keynesian model,[10]: 535 the "new neoclassical synthesis"[79][80]or simply the "new consensus" model.[79]
View post-2000 to present
[edit]A common view beginning around the year 2000 and holding through to the present time on inflation and its causes can be illustrated by a modern Phillips curve including a role for supply shocks and inflation expectations beside the original role of aggregate demand (determining employment and unemployment fluctuations) in influencing the inflation rate.[10]Consequently, demand shocks, supply shocks and inflation expectations are all potentially important determinants of inflation,[81]confirming the basis of the oldertriangle modelbyRobert J. Gordon:[82]
- Demand shocksmay both decrease and increase inflation. So-calleddemand-pull inflationmay be caused by increases in aggregate demand due to increased private and government spending,[83][84]etc. Conversely, negative demand shocks may be caused bycontractionaryeconomic policy.
- Supply shocksmay also lead to both higher or lower inflation, depending on the character of the shock.Cost-push inflationis caused by a drop in aggregate supply (potential output). This may be due to natural disasters, war or increased prices of inputs. For example, a sudden decrease in the supply of oil, leading to increased oil prices, can cause cost-push inflation. Producers for whom oil is a part of their costs could then pass this on to consumers in the form of increased prices.[85]
- Inflation expectationsplay a major role in forming actual inflation. High inflation can prompt employees to demand rapid wage increases to keep up with consumer prices. In this way, rising wages in turn can help fuel inflation as firms pass these higher labor costs on to their customers as higher prices, leading to a feedback loop. In the case of collective bargaining, wage growth may be set as a function of inflationary expectations, which will be higher when inflation is high. This can cause awage-price spiral.In a sense, inflation begets further inflationary expectations, which beget further(built-in) inflation.[85]
The important role of rational expectations is recognized by the emphasis on credibility on the part of central banks and otherpolicy-makers.[79]The monetarist assertion that monetary policy alone could successfully control inflation formed part of the new consensus which recognized that both monetary and fiscal policy are important tools for influencing aggregate demand.[79][10]: 528 Indeed, monetary policy is under normal circumstances considered to be the preferable instrument to contain inflation.[81][10]At the same time, most central banks have abandoned trying to target money growth as originally advocated by the monetarists. Instead, most central banks in developed countries focus on adjusting interest rates to achieve an explicit inflation target.[86][10]: 505–509 The reason for central bank reluctance in following money growth targets is that the money stock measures that central banks can control tightly, e.g. themonetary base,are not very closely linked to aggregate demand, whereas conversely money supply measures likeM2,which are in some cases more closely correlated with aggregate demand, are difficult to control for the central bank. Also, in many countries the relationship between aggregate demand and all money stock measures have broken down in recent decades, weakening further the case for monetary policy rules focusing on the money supply.[86]: 608
However, while more disputed in the 1970s, surveys of members of theAmerican Economic Association(AEA) since the 1990s have shown that most professional American economists generally agree with the statement "Inflation is caused primarily by too much growth in the money supply", while the same surveys have shown a lack of consensus by AEA members since the 1990s that "In the short run, a reduction in unemployment causes the rate of inflation to increase" has developed despite more agreement with the statement in the 1970s.[list 1]
Housing shortages[92][93][94][95]andclimate change[96][97][98][99]have both been cited as significant drivers of inflation in the 21st century.
2021–2022 inflation spike
[edit]In 2021–2022, most countries experienced a considerableincrease in inflation,peaking in 2022 and declining in 2023. The causes are believed to be a mixture of demand and supply shocks, whereas inflation expectations generally seem to remain anchored (as per May 2023).[100]Possible causes on the demand side include expansionary fiscal and monetary policy in the wake of the globalCOVID-19 pandemic,whereas supply shocks includesupply chainproblems also caused by the pandemic[100]and exacerbated by energy price rises following theRussian invasion of Ukrainein 2022.
The termsellers' inflationwas coined during this period to describe the effect of corporate profits as a possible cause of inflation: Price inelasticity can contribute to inflation whenfirms consolidate,tending to support monopoly ormonopsonyconditions anywhere along thesupply chainfor goods or services. When this occurs, firms can provide greatershareholder valueby taking a larger proportion ofprofitsthan by investing in providing greater volumes of their outputs.[101][102]Shortly after initial energy price shocks caused by the Russian invasion of Ukraine had subsided, oil companies found that supply chain constrictions, already exacerbated by the ongoing global pandemic, supported price inelasticity, i.e., they began lowering prices to match theprice of oilwhen it fell much more slowly than they had increased their prices when costs rose.[103]
Thequantity theory of moneyhas long been popular withlibertarian-conservativecritics of the Federal Reserve. During the COVID pandemic and its immediate aftermath, the M2 money supply increased at the fastest rate in decades, leading some to link the growth to the 2021-2023 inflation surge. Fed chairmanJerome Powellsaid in December 2021 that the once-strong link between the money supply and inflation "ended about 40 years ago," due to financial innovations and deregulation. Previous Fed chairsBen BernankeandAlan Greenspan,had previously concurred with this position. The broadest measure of money supply, M3, increased about 45% from 2010 through 2015, far faster than GDP growth, yet the inflation rate declined during that period — the opposite of what monetarism would have predicted. A lowervelocity of moneythan was historically the case[104]was also cited for a diminished effect of growth in the money supply on inflation.[105][106]
Heterodox views
[edit]Additionally, there are theories about inflation accepted by economists outside of themainstream.TheAustrian Schoolstresses that inflation is not uniform over all assets, goods, and services. Inflation depends on differences in markets and on where newly created money and credit enter the economy.Ludwig von Misessaid that inflation should refer to an increase in the quantity of money, that is not offset by a corresponding increase in the need for money, and that price inflation will necessarily follow, always leaving a poorer[107]nation.[108][109]
Effects of inflation
[edit]General effect
[edit]Inflation is the decrease in the purchasing power of a currency. That is, when the general level of prices rise, each monetary unit can buy fewer goods and services in aggregate. The effect of inflation differs on different sectors of the economy, with some sectors being adversely affected while others benefitting. For example, with inflation, those segments in society which own physical assets, such as property, stock etc., benefit from the price/value of their holdings going up, when those who seek to acquire them will need to pay more for them. Their ability to do so will depend on the degree to which their income is fixed. For example, increases in payments to workers and pensioners often lag behind inflation, and for some people income is fixed. Also, individuals or institutions with cash assets will experience a decline in the purchasing power of the cash. Increases in the price level (inflation) erode the real value of money (the functional currency) and other items with an underlying monetary nature.
Debtors who have debts with a fixed nominal rate of interest will see a reduction in the "real" interest rate as the inflation rate rises. The real interest on a loan is the nominal rate minus the inflation rate. The formulaR = N-Iapproximates the correct answer as long as both the nominal interest rate and the inflation rate are small. The correct equation isr = n/iwherer,nandiare expressed asratios(e.g. 1.2 for +20%, 0.8 for −20%). As an example, when the inflation rate is 3%, a loan with a nominal interest rate of 5% would have a real interest rate of approximately 2% (in fact, it's 1.94%). Any unexpected increase in the inflation rate would decrease the real interest rate. Banks and other lenders adjust for this inflation risk either by including an inflation risk premium to fixed interest rate loans, or lending at an adjustable rate.
Negative
[edit]High or unpredictable inflation rates are regarded as harmful to an overall economy. They add inefficiencies in the market, and make it difficult for companies to budget or plan long-term. Inflation can act as a drag on productivity as companies are forced to shift resources away from products and services to focus on profit and losses from currency inflation.[56]Uncertainty about the future purchasing power of money discourages investment and saving.[110]Inflation hurts asset prices such as stock performance in the short-run, as it erodes non-energy corporates' profit margins and leads to central banks' policy tightening measures.[111]Inflation can also impose hidden tax increases. For instance, inflated earnings push taxpayers into higher income tax rates unless the tax brackets are indexed to inflation.
With high inflation, purchasing power is redistributed from those on fixed nominal incomes, such as some pensioners whose pensions are not indexed to the price level, towards those with variable incomes whose earnings may better keep pace with the inflation.[56]This redistribution of purchasing power will also occur between international trading partners. Where fixedexchange ratesare imposed, higher inflation in one economy than another will cause the first economy's exports to become more expensive and affect thebalance of trade.There can also be negative effects to trade from an increased instability in currency exchange prices caused by unpredictable inflation.
- Hoarding
- People buy durable and/or non-perishable commodities and other goods as stores of wealth, to avoid the losses expected from the declining purchasing power of money, creating shortages of the hoarded goods.
- Social unrest and revolts
- Inflation can lead to massive demonstrations and revolutions. For example, inflation and in particularfood inflationis considered one of the main reasons that caused the 2010–2011Tunisian revolution[112]and the2011 Egyptian revolution,[113]according to many observers includingRobert Zoellick,[114]president of theWorld Bank.Tunisian presidentZine El Abidine Ben Aliwas ousted, Egyptian PresidentHosni Mubarakwas also ousted after only 18 days of demonstrations, and protests soon spread in many countries of North Africa and Middle East.
- Hyperinflation
- If inflation becomes too high, it can cause people to severely curtail their use of the currency, leading to an acceleration in the inflation rate. High and accelerating inflation grossly interferes with the normal workings of the economy, hurting its ability to supply goods. Hyperinflation can lead people to abandon the use of the country's currency in favour of external currencies (dollarization), as has been reported to have occurred inNorth Korea.[115]
- Corruption
- Due to a high rise of inflation,[Ströer Media 1]it has been seen to affect unemployment levels around the world. From 2005 to 2019, it was found that the wellbeing costs of unemployment was 5 times higher than inflation. The trust between the central banks and individuals has become more limited. According to the Global Labor Organization (GLO),[116]a global sample of 1.5 million observations during the 1999 and 2012 found a negative relationship of ECB unemployment between countries of Spain, Ireland, Greece, and Portugal a financial crisis.[117]Lack of trust is shown between the government and political institutions which potentially, this can create bias towards both sides as unemployment rate will still increase. If the rate goes on, predictions of the economic activity may decrease, and investments from around the world will soon slowdown creating a "economy crash" that can affect millions of peoples' living.[118]
- Allocative efficiency
- A change in the supply or demand for a good will normally cause itsrelative priceto change, signaling the buyers and sellers that they should re-allocate resources in response to the new market conditions. But when prices are constantly changing due to inflation, price changes due to genuine relativeprice signalsare difficult to distinguish from price changes due to general inflation, so agents are slow to respond to them. The result is a loss ofallocative efficiency.
- Shoe leather cost
- High inflation increases the opportunity cost of holding cash balances and can induce people to hold a greater portion of their assets in interest paying accounts. However, since cash is still needed to carry out transactions this means that more "trips to the bank" are necessary to make withdrawals, proverbially wearing out the "shoe leather" with each trip.
- With high inflation, firms must change their prices often to keep up with economy-wide changes. But often changing prices is itself a costly activity whether explicitly, as with the need to print new menus, or implicitly, as with the extra time and effort needed to change prices constantly.
Positive
[edit]- Labour-market adjustments
- Nominal wages areslow to adjust downward.This can lead to prolonged disequilibrium and high unemployment in the labor market. Since inflation allows real wages to fall even if nominal wages are kept constant, moderate inflation enables labor markets to reach equilibrium faster.[121]
- Room to maneuver
- The primary tools for controlling the money supply are the ability to set thediscount rate,the rate at which banks can borrow from the central bank, andopen market operations,which are the central bank's interventions into the bonds market with the aim of affecting the nominal interest rate. If an economy finds itself in a recession with already low, or even zero, nominal interest rates, then the bank cannot cut these rates further (since negative nominal interest rates are impossible) to stimulate the economy – this situation is known as aliquidity trap.
- Mundell–Tobin effect
- According to the Mundell–Tobin effect, an increase in inflation leads to an increase in capital investment, which leads to an increase in growth.[122]TheNobellaureateRobert Mundellnoted that moderate inflation would induce savers to substitute lending for some money holding as a means to finance future spending. That substitution would cause market clearing real interest rates to fall.[123]The lower real rate of interest would induce more borrowing to finance investment. In a similar vein, Nobel laureateJames Tobinnoted that such inflation would cause businesses to substitute investment inphysical capital(plant, equipment, and inventories) for money balances in their asset portfolios. That substitution would mean choosing the making of investments with lower rates of real return. (The rates of return are lower because the investments with higher rates of return were already being made before.)[124]The two related effects are known as theMundell–Tobin effect.Unless the economy is already overinvesting according to models ofeconomic growth theory,that extra investment resulting from the effect would be seen as positive.
- Instability with deflation
- EconomistS.C. Tsiangnoted that once substantial deflation is expected, two important effects will appear; both a result of money holding substituting for lending as a vehicle for saving.[125]The first was that continually falling prices and the resulting incentive to hoard money will cause instability resulting from the likely increasing fear, while money hoards grow in value, that the value of those hoards are at risk, as people realize that a movement to trade those money hoards for real goods and assets will quickly drive those prices up. Any movement to spend those hoards "once started would become a tremendous avalanche, which could rampage for a long time before it would spend itself."[126]Thus, a regime of long-term deflation is likely to be interrupted by periodic spikes of rapid inflation and consequent real economic disruptions. The second effect noted by Tsiang is that when savers have substituted money holding for lending on financial markets, the role of those markets in channeling savings into investment is undermined. With nominal interest rates driven to zero, or near zero, from the competition with a high return money asset, there would be no price mechanism in whatever is left of those markets. With financial markets effectively euthanized, the remaining goods and physical asset prices would move in perverse directions. For example, an increased desire to save could not push interest rates further down (and thereby stimulate investment) but would instead cause additional money hoarding, driving consumer prices further down and making investment in consumer goods production thereby less attractive. Moderate inflation, once its expectation is incorporated into nominal interest rates, would give those interest rates room to go both up and down in response to shifting investment opportunities, or savers' preferences, and thus allow financial markets to function in a more normal fashion.
Cost-of-living allowance
[edit]The real purchasing power of fixed payments is eroded by inflation unless they are inflation-adjusted to keep their real values constant. In many countries, employment contracts, pension benefits, and government entitlements (such associal security) are tied to a cost-of-living index, typically to theconsumer price index.[127]Acost-of-living adjustment(COLA) adjusts salaries based on changes in a cost-of-living index.[128]It does not control inflation, but rather seeks to mitigate the consequences of inflation for those on fixed incomes. Salaries are typically adjusted annually in low inflation economies. During hyperinflation they are adjusted more often.[127]They may also be tied to a cost-of-living index that varies by geographic location if the employee moves.
Annual escalation clauses in employment contracts can specify retroactive or future percentage increases in worker pay which are not tied to any index. These negotiated increases in pay are colloquially referred to as cost-of-living adjustments ( "COLAs" ) or cost-of-living increases because of their similarity to increases tied to externally determined indexes.
Controlling inflation
[edit]Monetary policyis the policy enacted by the monetary authorities (most frequently thecentral bankof a nation) to accomplish their objectives.[129]Among these, keeping inflation at a low and stable level is often a prominent objective, either directly viainflation targetingor indirectly, e.g. via afixed exchange rateagainst a low-inflation currency area.
Historical approaches to inflation control
[edit]Historically, central banks and governments have followed various policies to achieve low inflation, employing various nominal anchors. BeforeWorld War I,thegold standardwas prevalent, but was eventually found to be detrimental toeconomic stabilityand employment, not least during theGreat Depressionin the 1930s.[130]For the first decades afterWorld War II,theBretton Woods systeminitiated afixed exchange rate systemfor most developed countries, tying their currencies to the US dollar, which again was directly convertible to gold.[131]The system disintegrated in the 1970s, however, after which the major currencies started floating against each other.[132]During the 1970s many central banks turned to amoney supplytarget recommended byMilton Friedmanand othermonetarists,aiming for a stable growth rate of money to control inflation. However, it was found to be impractical because of the unstable relationship between monetary aggregates and other macroeconomic variables, and was eventually abandoned by all major economies.[130]In 1990, New Zealand as the first country ever adopted an officialinflation targetas the basis of its monetary policy, continually adjusting interest rates to steer the country's inflation rate towards its official target. The strategy was generally considered to work well, and central banks in mostdeveloped countrieshave over the years adapted a similar strategy.[133]As of 2023, the central banks of allG7member countries can be said to follow an inflation target, including theEuropean Central Bankand theFederal Reserve,who have adopted the main elements of inflation targeting without officially calling themselves inflation targeters.[133]In emerging countries fixed exchange rate regimes are still the most common monetary policy.[134]
Inflation targeting
[edit]From its first inception in New Zealand in 1990, direct inflation targeting as a monetary policy strategy has spread to become prevalent among developed countries. The basic idea is that the central bank perpetually adjusts interest rates to steer the country's inflation rate towards its official target. Via themonetary transmission mechanisminterest rate changes affectaggregate demandin various ways, causing output and employment to respond.[135]Changes in employment and unemployment rates affect wage setting, leading to larger or smaller wage increases, depending on the direction of the interest rate adjustment. A changed rate of wage increases will transmit into changes inprice setting– i.e. a change in the inflation rate. The relation between (un)employment and inflation is known as thePhillips curve.
In mostOECD countries,the inflation target is usually about 2% to 3% (in developing countries likeArmenia,the inflation target is higher, at around 4%).[136]Low (as opposed to zero ornegative) inflation reduces the severity of economic recessions by enabling the labor market to adjust more quickly in a downturn, and reduces the risk that aliquidity trapprevents monetary policy from stabilizing the economy.[12][13]
Fixed exchange rates
[edit]Under a fixed exchange rate currency regime, a country's currency is tied in value to another single currency or to a basket of other currencies. A fixed exchange rate is usually used to stabilize the value of a currency, vis-a-vis the currency it is pegged to. It can also be used as a means to control inflation if the currency area tied to itself maintains low and stable inflation. However, as the value of the reference currency rises and falls, so does the currency pegged to it. This essentially means that the inflation rate in the fixed exchange rate country is determined by the inflation rate of the country the currency is pegged to. In addition, a fixed exchange rate prevents a government from using domestic monetary policy to achieve macroeconomic stability.[137]
As of 2023,Denmarkis the onlyOECDcountry which maintains a fixed exchange rate (against theeuro), but it is frequently used as a monetary policy strategy in developing countries.[134]
Gold standard
[edit]The gold standard is a monetary system in which a region's common medium of exchange is paper notes (or other monetary token) that are normally freely convertible into pre-set, fixed quantities of gold. The standard specifies how the gold backing would be implemented, including the amount ofspecieper currency unit. The currency itself has noinnate valuebut is accepted by traders because it can be redeemed for the equivalent value of the commodity (specie). AU.S. silver certificate,for example, could be redeemed for an actual piece of silver.
Under a gold standard, the long term rate of inflation (or deflation) would be determined by the growth rate of the supply of gold relative to total output.[138]Critics argue that this will cause arbitrary fluctuations in the inflation rate, and that monetary policy would essentially be determined by an intersection of however much new gold was produced by mining and changing demand for gold for practical uses.[139][140]The gold standard was historically found to make it more difficult to stabilize employment levels and avoid recessions and was eventually abandoned everywhere.[130][141]
Wage and price controls
[edit]Another method attempted in the past have been wage andprice controls( "incomes policies" ). Temporary price controls may be used as a complement to other policies to fight inflation; price controls may make disinflation faster, while reducing the need for unemployment to reduce inflation. If price controls are used during a recession, the kinds of distortions that price controls cause may be lessened. However, economists generally advise against the imposition of price controls.[142][143][144]
Wage and price controls, in combination with rationing, have been used successfully in wartime environments. However, their use in other contexts is far more mixed. Notable failures of their use includethe 1972 imposition of wage and price controlsbyRichard Nixon.More successful examples include thePrices and Incomes Accordin Australia and theWassenaar Agreementin theNetherlands.
In general, wage and price controls are regarded as a temporary and exceptional measures, only effective when coupled with policies designed to reduce the underlying causes of inflation during thewage and pricecontrol regime, for example, winning the war being fought.
See also
[edit]- Artificial scarcity
- Core inflation
- Cost of living
- Food prices
- Hyperinflation
- Indexed unit of account
- Inflationism
- Inflation hedge
- Headline inflation
- List of countries by inflation rate
- Measuring economic worth over time
- Overconsumption
- Real versus nominal value (economics)
- ShrinkflationandSkimpflation
- Secular inflation
- Steady-state economy
- Stealth inflation
- Supply shock
- Welfare cost of inflation
- Template:Inflation– for price conversions in Wikipedia articles
Notes
[edit]- ^"Inflation worldwide – Statics & Facts".Statista.Einar H. Dyvik.RetrievedMarch 11,2024.
- ^"Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers (CPI-U): U.S. city average, by expenditure category, March 2022".Bureau of Labor Statistics.March 2022.RetrievedMarch 12,2022.
- ^"CPIH Annual Rate 00: All Items 2015=100".Office for National Statistics.April 13, 2022.Archivedfrom the original on April 24, 2022.RetrievedApril 13,2022.
- ^What Is Inflation?,Cleveland Federal Reserve, June 8, 2023, archived fromthe originalon March 30, 2021,retrievedJune 8,2023.
- ^"Overview of BLS Statistics on Inflation and Prices: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics".Bureau of Labor Statistics. June 5, 2019.Archivedfrom the original on December 10, 2021.RetrievedNovember 3,2021.
- ^Salwati, Nasiha; Wessel, David (June 28, 2021)."How does the government measure inflation?".Brookings Institution.Archivedfrom the original on November 15, 2021.RetrievedNovember 3,2021.
- ^"The Fed – What is inflation and how does the Federal Reserve evaluate changes in the rate of inflation?".Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.September 9, 2016.Archivedfrom the original on July 17, 2021.RetrievedNovember 3,2021.
- ^Why price stability?ArchivedOctober 14, 2008, at theWayback Machine,Central Bank of Iceland, Accessed on September 11, 2008.
- ^Paul H. Walgenbach, Norman E. Dittrich and Ernest I. Hanson, (1973), Financial Accounting, New York: Harcourt Brace Javonovich, Incorporated. P. 429. "The Measuring Unit principle: The unit of measure in accounting shall be the base money unit of the most relevant currency. This principle also assumes that the unit of measure is stable; that is, changes in its general purchasing power are not considered sufficiently important to require adjustments to the basic financial statements."
- ^Mankiw 2002,pp. 22–32.
- ^abcdefghijklmnopqrBlanchard (2021).
- ^Mankiw 2002,pp. 238–255.
- ^abHummel, Jeffrey Rogers."Death and Taxes, Including Inflation: the Public versus Economists".econjwatch.org.Econ Journal Watch: inflation, deadweight loss, deficit, money, national debt, seigniorage, taxation, velocity. p. 56.RetrievedNovember 19,2023.
- ^abSvensson, Lars E. O. (December 2003)."Escaping from a Liquidity Trap and Deflation: The Foolproof Way and Others".Journal of Economic Perspectives.17(4): 145–166.doi:10.1257/089533003772034934.ISSN0895-3309.S2CID17420811.
- ^"What is inflation? – Inflation, explained".Vox.July 25, 2014.Archivedfrom the original on August 4, 2014.RetrievedSeptember 13,2014.
- ^Bryan, Michael F. (October 15, 1997)."On the Origin and Evolution of the Word 'Inflation'".Economic Commentary(October 15, 1997). Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Commentary.Archivedfrom the original on October 28, 2021.RetrievedMay 22,2017.
- ^Blaug, Mark (March 27, 1997).Economic Theory in Retrospect.Cambridge University Press. p. 129.ISBN978-0-521-57701-4.
...this was the cause of inflation, or, to use the language of the day, 'the depreciation of banknotes.'
- ^Ashford, Kate (November 16, 2023)."What Is Deflation? Why Is It Bad For The Economy?".Forbes Advisor.RetrievedJanuary 30,2024.
- ^"Disinflation: Definition, How It Works, Triggers, and Example".Investopedia.RetrievedJanuary 30,2024.
- ^"Hyperinflation".Corporate Finance Institute.RetrievedJanuary 30,2024.
- ^"What Is Stagflation, What Causes It, and Why Is It Bad?".Investopedia.RetrievedJanuary 30,2024.
- ^"What Is Reflation?".The Balance.RetrievedJanuary 30,2024.
- ^"Asset-Price Inflation vs. Economic Growth".Investopedia.RetrievedJanuary 30,2024.
- ^"Agflation: What It Means, How It Works, Impact".Investopedia.RetrievedJanuary 30,2024.
- ^"UK House Price Index: November 2021".GOV.UK.RetrievedNovember 19,2023.
- ^Rubene, Ieva; Koester, Gerrit (May 6, 2021)."Recent dynamics in energy inflation: the role of base effects and taxes".ECB Economic Bulletin(3).
- ^abcdefghiParkin, Michael (2008). "Inflation".The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics:1–14.doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_888-2.ISBN978-1-349-95121-5.
- ^"Fiat Money: What It Is, How It Works, Example, Pros & Cons".Investopedia.RetrievedJanuary 30,2024.
- ^Corina, Pons; Luc, Cohen; O'Brien, Rosalba (November 7, 2018)."Venezuela's annual inflation hit 833,997 percent in October: Congress".Reuters.Archivedfrom the original on December 12, 2021.RetrievedNovember 9,2018.
- ^Bernholz, Peter (2015).Introduction.Edward Elgar Publishing.ISBN978-1-78471-763-6.Archivedfrom the original on June 18, 2021.RetrievedJune 9,2022.
- ^Baker, Gerard (January 19, 2007)."Welcome to 'the Great Moderation'".The Times.London: Times Newspapers.ISSN0140-0460.Archived fromthe originalon December 14, 2021.RetrievedApril 15,2011.
- ^Dobson, Roger (January 27, 2002)."How Alexander caused a great Babylon inflation".The Independent.Archived fromthe originalon May 15, 2011.RetrievedApril 12,2010.
- ^Harl, Kenneth W.(1996).Coinage in the Roman Economy, 300 B.C. to A.D. 700.Baltimore:The Johns Hopkins University Press.ISBN0-8018-5291-9.
- ^"Annual Report (2006), Royal Canadian Mint, p. 4"(PDF).Mint.ca.Archived(PDF)from the original on December 17, 2008.RetrievedMay 21,2011.
- ^Shostak, Frank (June 16, 2008)."Commodity Prices and Inflation: What's the Connection?".Mises Institute.RetrievedNovember 19,2023.
- ^von Glahn, Richard (1996).Fountain of Fortune: Money and Monetary Policy in China, 1000–1700.University of California Press. p. 48.ISBN978-0-520-20408-9.
- ^Ropp, Paul S. (2010).China in World History.Oxford University Press. p. 82.ISBN978-0-19-517073-3.
- ^Bernholz, Peter (2003).Monetary Regimes and Inflation: History, Economic and Political Relationships.Edward Elgar Publishing. pp. 53–55.ISBN978-1-84376-155-6.
- ^"Mansa Musa".May 24, 2006. Archived fromthe originalon May 24, 2006.RetrievedNovember 19,2023.
- ^"Kingdom of Mali – Primary Source Documents".African studies Center.Boston University.Archivedfrom the original on November 24, 2015.RetrievedJanuary 30,2012.
- ^Earl J. Hamilton,American Treasure and the Price Revolution in Spain, 1501–1650Harvard Economic Studies, p. 43 (Cambridge, Massachusetts:Harvard University Press,1934).
- ^"John Munro:The Monetary Origins of the 'Price Revolution':South Germany Silver Mining, Merchant Banking, and Venetian Commerce, 1470–1540,Toronto 2003 "(PDF).Archived fromthe original(PDF)on March 6, 2009.
- ^Walton, Timothy R. (1994).The Spanish Treasure Fleets.Florida, US: Pineapple Press. p. 85.ISBN1-56164-049-2.
- ^Bernholz, Peter; Kugler, Peter (August 1, 2007)."The Price Revolution in the 16th Century: Empirical Results from a Structural Vectorautoregression Model".Working Papers.Archivedfrom the original on April 25, 2021.RetrievedMarch 31,2015– via ideas.repec.org.
- ^Tracy, James D. (1994).Handbook of European History 1400–1600: Late Middle Ages, Renaissance, and Reformation.Boston: Brill Academic Publishers. p. 655.ISBN90-04-09762-7.
- ^Fischer, David Hackett (1996).The Great Wave.Oxford University Press. p. 81.ISBN0-19-512121-X.
- ^"What Does the Producer Price Index Tell You?".June 3, 2021.Archivedfrom the original on December 25, 2021.RetrievedOctober 1,2022.
- ^Kiley, Michael J. (July 2008)."Estimating the common trend rate of inflation for consumer prices and consumer prices excluding food and energy prices"(PDF).Finance and Economic Discussion Series. Federal Reserve Board.Archived(PDF)from the original on October 9, 2022.RetrievedMay 13,2015.
- ^See: The consumer price index measures movements in prices of a fixed basket of goods and services purchased by a "typical consumer".
- ^Carruthers, A. G.; Sellwood, D. J.; Ward, P. W. (1980)."Recent Developments in the Retail Prices Index".Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series D (The Statistician).29(1): 1–32.doi:10.2307/2987492.ISSN0039-0526.JSTOR2987492.Archivedfrom the original on June 9, 2022.RetrievedJune 9,2022.
- ^The numbers reported here refer to the US Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers, All Items, series CPIAUCNS, from base level 100 in base year 1982. They were downloaded from the FRED database at theFederal Reserve Bank of St. Louison August 8, 2008.
- ^Olson, Elizabeth (December 20, 2007)."The '12 Days' Index Shows a Record Increase".The New York Times.
- ^"Big MacCurrencies".The Economist.April 9, 1998.Archivedfrom the original on December 27, 2017.RetrievedNovember 27,2013.
- ^Erezi, Dennis (April 28, 2022)."Jollof Index, Chicken Republic, inflation and changing food consumption patterns".The Guardian Nigeria News - Nigeria and World News.RetrievedMay 15,2024.
- ^Eichholtz, Piet M. A. (1996)."A Long Run House Price Index: The Herengracht Index, 1628-1973".SSRN Electronic Journal.doi:10.2139/ssrn.598.ISSN1556-5068.
- ^"Lip service: What lipstick sales tell you about the economy".The Economist.January 23, 2009.ISSN0013-0613.RetrievedJune 10,2024.
- ^abcTaylor, Timothy (2008).Principles of Economics.Freeload Press.ISBN978-1-930789-05-0.
- ^Benchimol, Jonathan; Caspi, Itamar; Levin, Yuval (2022)."The COVID-19 Inflation Weighting in Israel".The Economists' Voice.19(1): 5–14.doi:10.1515/ev-2021-0023.S2CID245497122.
- ^Seiler, Pascal (September 16, 2020)."Weighting bias and inflation in the time of COVID-19: evidence from Swiss transaction data".Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics.156(1): 13.doi:10.1186/s41937-020-00057-7.ISSN2235-6282.PMC7493696.PMID32959014.
- ^Botella, Elena (November 8, 2019)."That" Inflation Inequality "Report Has a Major Problem".Slate.Archivedfrom the original on November 30, 2021.RetrievedNovember 11,2019.
- ^Vavra, Joseph (2014)."Inflation Dynamics and Time-Varying Volatility: New Evidence and an SS Interpretation".The Quarterly Journal of Economics.129(1): 215–258.doi:10.1093/qje/qjt027.RetrievedMarch 22,2023.
- ^Arlt, Josef (March 11, 2021)."The problem of annual inflation rate indicator".International Journal of Finance & Economics.28(3): 2772–2788.doi:10.1002/ijfe.2563.S2CID233675877.
- ^Kenton, Will."Why Core Inflation is Important".Investopedia.Archivedfrom the original on December 14, 2021.RetrievedJanuary 17,2020.
- ^"Median Price Changes: An Alternative Approach to Measuring Current Monetary Inflation"(PDF).Archived fromthe original(PDF)on May 15, 2011.RetrievedMay 21,2011.
- ^Wroughton, Lesley (February 2, 2013)."IMF reprimands Argentina for inaccurate economic data".Reuters.Archivedfrom the original on August 4, 2021.RetrievedFebruary 2,2013.
- ^"Argentina Becomes First Nation Censured by IMF on Economic Data".Bloomberg.com.February 2, 2013.Archivedfrom the original on March 10, 2021.RetrievedFebruary 2,2013.
- ^"You Decide: Why Stop at an Inflation Rate Target of 2%?".CALS News.NC State University. January 29, 2023.
- ^Dan Richards; Manzur Rashid; Peter Antonioni (November 1, 2016)."Why Inflation Is Usually Overestimated".John Wiley & Sons.
- ^ab"The naked eye versus the CPI: How does our perception of inflation stack up against the data?".Statistics Canada. January 19, 2022.
- ^"University of Michigan: Inflation Expectation".Economic Research, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. January 1978.Archivedfrom the original on November 7, 2021.RetrievedMarch 9,2017.
- ^abDimand, Robert W. (2016)."Monetary Economics, History of".The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics.Palgrave Macmillan UK. pp. 1–13.doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_2721-1.ISBN978-1-349-95121-5.
- ^Green, Roy (2018). "Real Bills Doctrine".The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics:11328–11330.doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1614.ISBN978-1-349-95188-8.
- ^Schwartz, Anna J. (2018). "Banking School, Currency School, Free Banking School".The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics:694–700.doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_263.ISBN978-1-349-95188-8.
- ^Humphrey, Thomas M.; Timberlake, Richard H. (2019).Gold, the Real Bills Doctrine, and the Fed: sources of monetary disorder 1922–1938(First ed.). Washington, D.C.: Cato Institute.ISBN978-1-948647-13-7.
- ^Friedman, Milton; Schwartz, Anna Jacobson (1963).A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960.Princeton University Press.
- ^abLagassé, Paul (2000). "Monetarism".The Columbia Encyclopedia(6th ed.). New York: Columbia University Press.ISBN0-7876-5015-3.
- ^abMankiw (2022).
- ^Coe, David T. (1985)."Nominal Wages. The NAIRU and Wage Flexibility"(PDF).OECD Economic Studies(5). Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD): 87–126.S2CID18879396.MPRA Paper 114295.Archived(PDF)from the original on February 26, 2018.RetrievedFebruary 24,2010.
- ^Chang, R. (1997)"Is Low Unemployment Inflationary?"ArchivedNovember 13, 2013, at theWayback MachineFederal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review1Q97: 4–13.
- ^abcdGoodfriend, Marvin (November 1, 2007)."How the World Achieved Consensus on Monetary Policy".Journal of Economic Perspectives.21(4): 47–68.doi:10.1257/jep.21.4.47.S2CID56338417.
- ^Woodford, Michael (January 1, 2009). "Convergence in Macroeconomics: Elements of the New Synthesis".American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics.1(1): 267–279.doi:10.1257/mac.1.1.267.
- ^ab"Inflation in the U.S. Economy: Causes and Policy Options".crsreports.congress.gov.Congressional Research Service. October 6, 2022.RetrievedOctober 15,2023.
- ^Robert J. Gordon (1988),Macroeconomics: Theory and Policy,2nd ed., Chap. 22.4, 'Modern theories of inflation'. McGraw-Hill.
- ^Gillespie, Nick; Taylor, Regan (April 2022)."Biden Is Clueless About Inflation".reason.com.Reason.Archivedfrom the original on April 27, 2022.RetrievedApril 4,2022.
- ^De Rugy, Veronique (March 31, 2022)."Blame Insane Government Spending for Inflation".reason.com.Reason.Archivedfrom the original on May 11, 2022.RetrievedApril 4,2022.
- ^ab"Encyclopædia Britannica".Archivedfrom the original on September 7, 2014.RetrievedSeptember 13,2014.
- ^abRomer, David (2019).Advanced macroeconomics(Fifth ed.). New York, New York: McGraw-Hill.ISBN978-1-260-18521-8.
- ^Kearl, J. R.; Pope, Clayne L.; Whiting, Gordon C.; Wimmer, Larry T. (1979). "A Confusion of Economists?".American Economic Review.69(2). American Economic Association: 28–37.JSTOR1801612.
- ^Alston, Richard M.;Kearl, J.R.;Vaughan, Michael B. (May 1992)."Is There a Consensus Among Economists in the 1990's?"(PDF).The American Economic Review.82(2): 203–209.JSTOR2117401.
- ^Fuller, Dan; Geide-Stevenson, Doris (Fall 2003). "Consensus Among Economists: Revisited".The Journal of Economic Education.34(4): 369–387.doi:10.1080/00220480309595230.JSTOR30042564.S2CID143617926.
- ^Fuller, Dan; Geide-Stevenson, Doris (2014)."Consensus Among Economists – An Update".The Journal of Economic Education.45(2).Taylor & Francis:138.doi:10.1080/00220485.2014.889963.S2CID143794347.
- ^Geide-Stevenson, Doris; La Parra-Perez, Alvaro (2022).Consensus among economists 2020 – A sharpening of the picture.Western Economic Association International Annual Conference.RetrievedOctober 13,2023.
- ^Derby, Michael S. (September 27, 2022)."Fed's Harker says housing shortage a key inflation driver".Reuters.
- ^O'Donnell, Katy; Guida, Victoria (November 10, 2021)."Biden's next inflation threat: The rent is too damn high".Politico.
Housing costs just posted one of their largest monthly gains in decades, and many economists expect them to loom large in inflation figures over the next year heading into the 2022 midterm elections. It's not just economists — the Federal Reserve Bank of New York said in research released Monday that Americans on average expect rents to rise 10.1 percent over the next year, the highest reading in the survey's history.
- ^Boak, Josh (March 15, 2024)."Why are so many voters frustrated by the US economy? It's home prices".AP News.RetrievedJuly 24,2024.
- ^O'Donnell, Katy (March 18, 2022)."The main driver of inflation isn't what you think it is".Politico.
But when it comes to the single biggest driver of runaway prices, Washington's hands are mostly tied. Skyrocketing housing costs may create even bigger problems for the administration going forward than oil and food price spikes, which are the result of sudden and unforeseen — but probably temporary — events. That's because there's no clear end in sight for shelter inflation.
- ^Borenstein, Seth (March 21, 2024)."Higher temperatures mean higher food and other prices. A new study links climate shocks to inflation".AP News.RetrievedJuly 24,2024.
- ^"Home insurance rates are rising due to climate change. What could break that cycle?".NPR.July 23, 2024.
- ^Becker, William S. (July 22, 2024)."Opinion: Climate inflation is eating your paycheck — and it's only going to get worse".The Hill.RetrievedJuly 24,2024.
- ^"How is climate change affecting food prices and inflation?".Al Jazeera.July 11, 2024.RetrievedJuly 24,2024.
- ^abBernanke, Ben; Blanchard, Olivier (May 23, 2023)."What Caused the U.S. Pandemic-Era Inflation?"(PDF).www.brookings.edu.Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy at the Brookings Institution.RetrievedOctober 15,2023.
- ^Mankiw, N. Gregory (2015). "Part V, chapters 13–17".Principles of economics(Seventh ed.). Stamford, Connecticut:Cengage Learning.pp. 257–367.ISBN978-1285165875.
- ^Bivins, Josh (April 21, 2022)."Corporate profits have contributed disproportionately to inflation. How should policymakers respond?".Economic Policy Institute.Archivedfrom the original on May 25, 2022.RetrievedMay 25,2022.
- ^Cronin, Brittany (May 7, 2022)."The good times are rolling for Big Oil. 3 things to know about their surging profits".NPR.Archivedfrom the original on May 21, 2022.RetrievedMay 25,2022.
- ^"Velocity of M2 Money Stock".Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
- ^Hanke, Steve H.; John Greenwood (January 15, 2024)."Inflation Was Always a Monetary Phenomenon, Never Transitory".National Review.
- ^Lynch, David J. (February 6, 2022)."Inflation has Fed critics pointing to spike in money supply".The Washington Post.
- ^Mises, Ludwig von."Human Action".OLL.Archivedfrom the original on September 25, 2021.RetrievedJuly 17,2021.
- ^Von Mises, Ludwig (1912).The Theory of Money and Credit(PDF)(1953 ed.). Yale University Press. p. 240.Archived(PDF)from the original on October 9, 2022.RetrievedJanuary 23,2014.
In theoretical investigation there is only one meaning that can rationally be attached to the expression Inflation: an increase in the quantity of money (in the broader sense of the term, so as to include fiduciary media as well), that is not offset by a corresponding increase in the demand for money (again in the broader sense of the term), so that a fall in the objective exchange-value of money must occur.
- ^The Theory of Money and Credit, Mises (1912, [1981]), p. 272.
- ^Bulkley, George (March 1981). "Personal Savings and Anticipated Inflation".The Economic Journal.91(361): 124–135.doi:10.2307/2231702.JSTOR2231702.
- ^"Stock Returns and Inflation Redux: An Explanation from Monetary Policy in Advanced and Emerging Markets".IMF.Archivedfrom the original on January 8, 2023.RetrievedJanuary 8,2023.
- ^"Les Egyptiens souffrent aussi de l'accélération de l'inflation", Céline Jeancourt-Galignani – La Tribune, February 10, 2011.
- ^AFP (January 27, 2011)."Egypt protests a ticking time bomb: Analysts".The New Age. Archived fromthe originalon February 9, 2011.RetrievedJanuary 29,2011.
- ^"Les prix alimentaires proches de 'la cote d'alerte'" – Le Figaro, with AFP, February 20, 2011.
- ^Hanke, Steve H. (July 2013)."North Korea: From Hyperinflation to Dollarization?".Cato Institute.Archivedfrom the original on December 26, 2020.RetrievedAugust 21,2014.
- ^"Organization".Global Labor Organization.July 28, 2017.RetrievedMarch 11,2024.
- ^Popova, Olga; See, Sarah Grace; Nikolova, Milena; Otrachshenko, Vladimir (2023)."The societal costs of inflation and unemployment"(PDF).Global Labor Organization.EconStor.Archived(PDF)from the original on March 13, 2024.RetrievedMarch 11,2024.
- ^Claessens, Stijin; Kose, M. Ayhan."Recession: When Bad Times Prevail".F&D.IMF.RetrievedMarch 11,2024.
- ^Cooley, Thomas F.; Hansen, Gary D. (1989)."The Inflation Tax in a Real Business Cycle Model".The American Economic Review.79(4): 733–748.ISSN0002-8282.JSTOR1827929.Archivedfrom the original on October 8, 2021.RetrievedOctober 7,2021.
- ^"Inflation: A Tax on Money Holdings".www.economics.utoronto.ca.Archivedfrom the original on November 11, 2020.RetrievedOctober 7,2021.
- ^Tobin, James (1972)."Inflation and Unemployment".American Economic Review.62(1): 1–18.JSTOR1821468.RetrievedMarch 22,2023.
- ^Edwards, Jeffrey A. (2006)."Politics, Inflation, and the Mundell–Tobin Effect".mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de.Archivedfrom the original on November 1, 2018.RetrievedJune 9,2022.
- ^Mundell, James (1963). "Inflation and Real Interest".Journal of Political Economy.LXXI(3): 280–283.doi:10.1086/258771.S2CID153733633.
- ^Tobin, J.Econometrica,Vol. 33, (1965), pp. 671–684 "Money and Economic Growth"
- ^Tsiang, S. C. (1969)."A Critical Note on the Optimum Supply of Money".Journal of Money, Credit and Banking.1(2): 266–280.doi:10.2307/1991274.JSTOR1991274.Archivedfrom the original on April 25, 2021.RetrievedOctober 20,2020.
- ^Tsiang, 1969 (p. 272).
- ^abFlanagan, Tammy (September 8, 2006)."COLA Wars".Government Executive.National Journal Group.Archived fromthe originalon October 5, 2008.RetrievedSeptember 23,2008.
- ^Kunkel, Sue."Cost-Of-Living Adjustment (COLA)".www.ssa.gov.Archivedfrom the original on November 27, 2021.RetrievedMay 15,2018.
- ^Lindsey, D. E.; Wallich, H. C. (2018). "Monetary Policy". In:The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics.London: Palgrave Macmillan. Retrieved September 17, 2023.
- ^abc"Federal Reserve Board – Historical Approaches to Monetary Policy".Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.March 8, 2018.RetrievedSeptember 17,2023.
- ^"About the IMF: History: Cooperation and reconstruction (1944–1971)".www.imf.org.RetrievedSeptember 17,2023.
- ^"About the IMF: History: The end of the Bretton Woods System (1972–1981)".www.imf.org.RetrievedSeptember 17,2023.
- ^ab"Inflation Targeting: Holding the Line".www.imf.org.RetrievedSeptember 17,2023.
- ^abDepartment, International Monetary Fund Monetary and Capital Markets (2023).Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2022.International Monetary Fund.ISBN979-8-4002-3526-9.RetrievedAugust 12,2023.
- ^"Federal Reserve Board – Monetary Policy: What Are Its Goals? How Does It Work?".Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.July 29, 2021.RetrievedSeptember 17,2023.
- ^"Inflation Reports".www.cba.am.Archivedfrom the original on December 6, 2022.RetrievedDecember 6,2022.
- ^Blanchard, Olivier; Amighini, Alessia; Giavazzi, Francesco (2017). "Output, the interest rate and the exchange rate".Macroeconomics: a European perspective(3rd ed.). Harlow, London, New York, Boston, San Francisco, Toronto, Sydney, Dubai, Singapore, Hong Kong, Tokyo, Seoul, Taipei, New Delhi, Cape Town, Sao Paulo, Mexico City, Madrid, Amsterdam, Muinch, Paris, Milan: Pearson.ISBN978-1-292-08567-8.
- ^Bordo, Michael D. (2002)."Gold Standard".The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics.Library of Economics and Liberty.Archivedfrom the original on October 5, 2010.RetrievedSeptember 23,2008.
- ^Barsky, Robert B.; DeLong, J. Bradford (1991)."Forecasting Pre-World War I Inflation: The Fisher Effect and the Gold Standard".Quarterly Journal of Economics.106(3): 815–836.doi:10.2307/2937928.JSTOR2937928.Archivedfrom the original on June 20, 2015.RetrievedSeptember 27,2008.
- ^DeLong, Brad."Why Not the Gold Standard?".Archived fromthe originalon October 18, 2010.RetrievedSeptember 25,2008.
- ^Abdel-Monem, Tarik."What is The Gold Standard?".University of Iowa Center for The Center for International Finance and Development. Archived fromthe originalon November 21, 2009.
- ^"Why Price Controls Should Stay in the History Books".www.stlouisfed.org.RetrievedSeptember 5,2024.
- ^Committee, United States Joint Economic."The Economics of Price Controls - The Economics of Price Controls - United States Joint Economic Committee".www.jec.senate.gov.RetrievedSeptember 5,2024.
- ^"Price Controls: Still A Bad Idea".Hoover Institution.RetrievedSeptember 5,2024.
- Bundled references
References
[edit]- Abel, Andrew B.;Bernanke, Ben S.;Croushore, Dean (2005).Macroeconomics(5th ed.). Pearson.ISBN978-0-32119963-8.Measurement of inflation is discussed in Ch. 2, pp. 45–50; Money growth & Inflation in Ch. 7, pp. 266–269; Keynesian business cycles and inflation in Ch. 9, pp. 308–348.
- Barro, Robert J.(1997).Macroeconomics.Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. p. 895.ISBN0-262-02436-5.
- Blanchard, Olivier(2021).Macroeconomics(Eighth, global ed.). Harlow, England: Pearson.ISBN978-0-134-89789-9.
- Mankiw, N. Gregory(2002).Macroeconomics(5th ed.). Worth.ISBN978-0-71675237-0.Measurement of inflation is discussed in Ch. 2, pp. 22–32; Money growth & Inflation in Ch. 4, pp. 81–107; Keynesian business cycles and inflation in Ch. 9, pp. 238–255.
- Hall, Robert E.;Taylor, John B.(1993).Macroeconomics.New York: W.W. Norton. p.637.ISBN0-393-96307-1.
- Burda, Michael C.;Wyplosz, Charles (1997).Macroeconomics: a European text.Oxford [Oxfordshire]:Oxford University Press.ISBN0-19-877468-0.
Further reading
[edit]- World Bank, 2018.Inflation in Emerging and Developing Economies: Evolution, Drivers and Policies.Edited by Jongrim Ha, M. Ayhan Kose, and Franziska Ohnsorge.
- Auernheimer, Leonardo,"The Honest Government's Guide to the Revenue From the Creation of Money", Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 82, No. 3, May/June 1974, pp. 598–606.
- Baumol, William J.andAlan S. Blinder,Macroeconomics: Principles and Policy,Tenth edition. Thomson South-Western, 2006.ISBN0-324-22114-2.
- Friedman, Milton,Nobel lecture:Inflation and unemployment1977.
- Mishkin, Frederic S.,The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets,New York, HarperCollins, 1995.
- Federal Reserve Bank of Boston,"Understanding Inflation and the Implications for Monetary Policy: A Phillips Curve Retrospective"ArchivedAugust 26, 2013, at theWayback Machine,Conference Series 53, June 9–11, 2008, Chatham, Massachusetts. (Also cf.Phillips curvearticle).