Jump to content

Farm (revenue leasing)

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected fromTax farming)

Farmingortax-farmingis a technique offinancial managementin which the management of a variable revenue stream is assigned bylegal contractto a third party and the holder of the revenue stream receives fixed periodic rents from the contractor. It is most commonly used inpublic finance,where governments (thelessors) lease or assign the right to collect and retain the whole of the tax revenue to a private financier (the farmer), who is charged with paying fixed sums (sometimes called "rents", but with a different meaning from the common modern term) into thetreasury.

Farming in this sense has nothing to do withagriculture,other than in a metaphorical sense.

Etymology[edit]

There are two possible origins forfarm.

Derivation from classical Latin[edit]

Some sources derive "farm" with its French versionferme,most notably used in the context of theFermiers Generaux,from the mediaeval Latinfirma,meaning "a fixed agreement, contract", ultimately from the classical Latin adjectivefirmus,firma,firmum,meaning "firm, strong, stout, steadfast, immoveable, sure, to be relied upon".[1]The modern agricultural sense of the word stems from the same origin, in that a medieval land- "holder" (none "owned" land but the king himself under hisallodialtitle) underfeudal land tenuremight let it (i.e. lease it out) under a contract as agoing concern(not as asub-infeudatedfee), that is to say as a unit producing a revenue stream, together with its workers and livestock, for exploitation by a tenant who was licensed by the contract, orfirma,to keep all the revenue he could extract from the holding in exchange for fixed rents. Thus the rights to the revenue stream produced by the land had been farmed by the lessor. Because this was the form of the farming transaction most known to popular society, the word "farmer" became synonymous with a tenant of an agricultural holding.

Derivation from Old English[edit]

According to other sources, the wordfarmcomes fromMiddle Englishferme( "farm, rent, revenue; revenue collected from a farmer; factor, stewardship, meal, feast" ), fromOld Englishfeorm, farm( "provision, stores of food, supplies, possessions; provisions supplied to the king or a lord by a tenant or vassal; rent, feast, benefit, assylum" ), fromProto-Germanic*firmō, *firχumō( "means of living, subsistence" ), fromProto-Indo-European*perkwu-( "life, strength, force" ). It is related to other Old English words such asfeormehām( "farm" ),feormere( "purveyor, grocer" ),feormian( "to provision, sustain" ), andfeorh( "life, spirit" ). The Old English word is stated by these sources as having unusually been borrowed byMedieval Latinasfirmaorfermaand to have provided theOld Frenchferme"farm",Occitanferma"farm". This is refuted by those sources which statefirmato derive from classical Latinfirmus.[2]The word continued the same senses of "rent, farmed office, source of revenue, feast". The meaning "rent, fixed payment", which was already present in the Old English word, was further strengthened due to the word's resemblance to the unrelated (so say these sources)Latinfirmus( "firm, solid" ), andfirmitas( "security, firmness" ).[3][4]

Valuation of a farm[edit]

The tenant of a farm can only make a profit after carefully assessing its value. While modern financial management theory employs scientific formulae for such calculations, astute financiers of the past would have understood them well, whether done mentally or by making marks in the sand.

To determine the maximum rent they are willing to pay, the tenant estimates the long-term average yearly gross value of the revenue stream, based on past records and accounts, adjusting for any new circumstances affecting the future. They then deduct a risk element and a discount for the time value of money.

The risk is related to the possibility of some debts forming the revenue stream being defaulted on or paid late, leading to variability in the revenue. The resulting figure becomes the maximum rent the tenant offers to the farm's lessor. The tenant's profit is the excess of revenues extracted from the farm, less the rents, administration, levying, and collection expenses.

The tenant's skills lie in negotiating a favorable rent by overstating the riskiness of the cash flow stream and effectively managing the assigned debts as a skilled debt-collector and manager. They must ensure their ability to enforce debt payments, including resorting to legal action and paying standard fees for bringing a lawsuit under the government authority that is the farm's lessor. The tenant acts as a principal, not the lessor's agent.

Historical use[edit]

Roman Empire[edit]

Tax farming was originally aRomanpractice whereby the burden oftax collectionwas reassigned by the Roman State to private individuals or groups. In essence, these individuals or groups paid the taxes for a certain area and for a certain period of time and then attempted to cover their outlay by collecting money or saleable goods from the people within that area.[5]The system was set up byGaius Gracchusin 123 BC primarily to increase the efficiency of tax collection withinRomeitself but the system quickly spread to theProvinces.[6]Within the Roman Empire, these private individuals and groups which collected taxes in lieu of the bid (i.e. rent) they had paid to the state were known aspublicani,of whom the best known is thedisciple of JesusMatthew the Apostle,apublicanusin the village ofCapernaumin the province ofGalilee.The system was widely abused, and reforms were enacted byAugustusandDiocletian.[7]Tax farming practices are believed to have contributed to thefall of the Western Roman Empirein Western Europe.[8]

Feudal England[edit]

Medieval English kings frequently made grants "infee-farm ", a form offeudal tenure.An example is the followingwritof KingWilliam II(1087–1100) granting ahundred courtto be held in fee-farm byThorney Abbey:

William, king of the English, to all thesheriffsandbaronsofHuntingdonshire,greeting. Know that I have granted theHundred of Normancrossto theabbotand monks of Thorney to be held in fee-farm for an annual rent of 100shillingswhich I order them to pay to my sheriff at Huntingdon. And I forbid any of my officers to do them injury or insult in respect of this.[9]

Medieval Egypt[edit]

TheChief RabbiofEgypt,Sar Shalom ben Moseswas accused of tax farming, which led to his excommunication byMaimonides.[10]

Ottoman Empire[edit]

Theiltizam(Ottoman Turkish:التزام) is a non-heritable tax-farming system and was established under SultanMehmet II;however this changed by the 18th century and holders of grants-for-life (malikâne) developed their own landowning class.[11]It was officially terminated in 1856 during theTanzimatreforms.[12]

Other uses[edit]

Besides the Romans, historical examples include the tax collection methods of thePtolemies,Seljuks,Mamluks,Ottomans,theFrench State prior to Louis XVI(seeferme générale), andRussiaprior to 1862 and theDutch East Indies(seepacht) prior to the twentieth century. In many cases, such as theAbbasidpractice ofIqta,these rights were granted by an authority, in this example the caliph, for services rendered or promised. In the Byzantinepronoiasystem, similar rights were often purchased from the crown. Though such arrangements in some respects seem similar to the feudal system, there are significant disparities, including continuance of state power and, at least in the case ofpronoia,theoretical time limits on the grant. In many cases, including those mentioned, tax rights were not transferable or divisible, unlike feudal fiefdoms.

Sometimes, as in the case ofMiguel de Cervantes,the tax farmer was a government employee, paid a salary, and all money collected went to the government.[citation needed]

Advantages[edit]

Tax farming was an important step in the history ofeconomic developmentby providing a method for collecting taxes across a large area without the need for a tax-collectingbureaucracy,or during periods when such a bureaucracy is unworkable or impossible to maintain. Systems of tax farming similar to the Roman model were used inPtolemaic Egypt,various medieval Western European countries, theOttomanandMughalempires, and inQing dynastyChina. As states become stronger, buoyed up by revenues brought in by tax farming, the practice was discontinued in favour of centralized tax collection systems. In part this was because tax farming systems tended to rely on wealthy individuals outside the state machinery,gangs,andsecret societies.[13]

Disadvantages[edit]

The key flaw in the tax farming system is the tension between the state, which seeks a long-term source of taxation revenue, and the tax farmers, who seek to make a profit on their investment in as short a time as possible. As a result, tax-farmers often abuse the taxpayers in various ways, tending them to switch their economic activity from strategic long-term projects to short-term revenue generation. Inbartersystems, tax farmers commonly undervaluetaxes in kind,reselling the goods to create a second profit source. Such abuses stifle economic growth by restricting the ability of the tradesman to reinvest in his business, limiting the quantity of taxes generated over the long-term.[citation needed]

Modern-day[edit]

Indian sub-continent[edit]

In Bangladesh and India tolls on bridges and roads and dues from public properties such as lakes and forests are often leased to private persons or firms.[citation needed]

United States of America[edit]

After the 2008 financial crisis, the city of Chicago needed money and a deal was made to sell all 36,000[4] of the parking meter spots in the city for 75 years for 1.15 billion dollars to a firm calledChicago Parking Meters.

Disambiguation[edit]

Privatized tax collection[edit]

Tax farming is not synonymous with modernprivatized tax collection,where private individuals or companies collect taxes and pass them to the state in return for a commission or fee, without bearing any risk consequent of default by the taxpayer. Tax farming isspeculative,meaning that the tenant of the farm bears the full risk of defaulted debts. In addition, a tenant is often required as a term of the lease to make an early rent payment, which must be financed from his own resources until the revenue stream subject to the farm has started to be collected.

Factoring[edit]

In theUnited Kingdom,some tax collection of "lower value debts" byHMRChas been outsourced todebt collection agenciesfrom July 2010.[14]However, debt collection agencies, like invoice factors, are not truly farmers of revenue streams, as they do not bear any risk of default. Rather they make loans in expectation of future receipts, such loans being always recoverable and secured on the income stream itself.

Simple commutation[edit]

In 1999 the National Board of Revenue in Bangladesh (NBR) negotiated with cigarette producing firms a minimum amount ofvalue added tax(VAT) that should be paid per month even though VAT is anad valoremtax, that is to say of variable yield. The NBR took this step because under the self-clearance system monitoring of production and sales of cigarettes proved to be difficult. It was agreed that if the cigarette producing firms paid the minimum revenue fixed by the NBR, physical monitoring would be withdrawn. The NBR resorted to this technique of financial management to avoid the large costs of monitoring while gaining more in revenue with certainty.[15]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^Larousse Dictionnaire de la Langue FrancaiseLexis,Paris, 1993 "Ferme: contrat par lequel un proprietaire abandonne a un locataire l'exploitation d'un domaine moyennant le paiement d'un loyer" (contract by which a proprietor transfers the exploitation of a holding to a tenant by means of the payment of a rent); Cassell's Latin Dictionary, ed. Marchant & Charles
  2. ^Larousse, op.cit.
  3. ^Century Dictionary and Cyclopedia, "farm".
  4. ^Mantello, Rigg,Medieval Latin: an introduction and bibliographical guide,11.3
  5. ^Howatson M. C.: Oxford Companion to Classical Literature, Oxford University Press, 1989,ISBN0-19-866121-5
  6. ^Balsdon J.: Roman Civilization, Pelican, 1965
  7. ^Roman-taxesat unrv.com
  8. ^Cahill, Thomas.How the Irish saved civilization: the untold story of Ireland's heroic role from the fall of Rome to the rise of medieval Europe.Anchor Books, Doubleday, 1996, p. 26.
  9. ^Douglas, David C. & Greenaway, George W., (eds.), English Historical Documents 1042–1189, London, 1959. Part II, Government & Administration, part C, The Sheriff & Local Government, p. 433
  10. ^Rustow, Marina (2010-10-01)."Sar Shalom ben Moses ha-Levi".Encyclopedia of Jews in the Islamic World.
  11. ^Hourani, Albert (1991).A History of the Arab Peoples.England, UK: Faber and Faber Limited. p. 234.ISBN978-0-674-39565-7.
  12. ^"Iltizām | tax system".Encyclopedia Britannica.Retrieved2021-09-23.
  13. ^John Butcher and Howard Dick,The Rise and Fall of Revenue Farming: Business Elites and the Emergence of the Modern State.St. Martin's Press, 1993
  14. ^[1]Archived2011-05-14 at theWayback Machine[2]Archived2010-07-31 at theWayback Machine
  15. ^Chowdhury, Faizul L.NBR's attempt at Tax Farming - fixed amount of VAT on Cigarettes in 1999,2007: Desh Prokashon, Dhaka.

Further reading[edit]

  • Chowdhury, F. L. (2007),NBR's attempt at Tax Farming – fixed VAT on Cigarettes in 1999,Desh Prokashon, Dhaka.
  • Levi, M. Of (1988),Rule and Revenue,California Series on Social Choice and Political Economy (13), University of California Press.
  • Stella, P. (1992),Tax Farming: A Radical Solution for Developing Country Tax Problems?(September 1992). IMF Working Paper No. 92/70.

External links[edit]