Jump to content

Cliometrics

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Cliometrics(/ˌkl.əˈmɛt.rɪks/,also/ˌklˈmɛt.rɪks/), sometimes called 'new economic history'[1]or 'econometric history',[2]is the systematic application of economic theory,econometrictechniques, and other formal or mathematical methods to the study of history (especiallysocialandeconomic history).[3]It is aquantitativeapproach to economic history (as opposed toqualitativeorethnographic).[4]

There has been a revival in 'new economic history' since the late 1990s.[5][6]

CliobyPierre Mignard,oil on canvas, 1689

History[edit]

The new economic history originated in 1958 withThe Economics of Slavery in the Antebellum Southby American economistsAlfred H. ConradandJohn R. Meyer.The book would cause a firestorm of controversy with its claim, based on statistical data, that slavery would not have ended in the absence of the U.S. Civil War, as the practice was economically efficient and highly profitable for slaveowners.[4][7]

The termcliometrics—which derives fromClio,who was themuseof history—was originally coined bymathematical economistStanley Reiterin 1960.[8]Cliometrics became better known whenDouglass Northand William Parker became the editors of theJournal of Economic Historyin 1960. The Cliometrics Meetings also began to be held around this time atPurdue Universityand are still held annually in different locations.

North, a professor at Washington University in St. Louis, would go on to win theNobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciencesin October 1993 along withRobert William Fogel,himself often described as the father of modern econometric history and Neo-historicals.[9][10]The two were honoured "for having renewed research in economic history;" the Academy noted that "they were pioneers in the branch of economic history that has been called the 'new economic history,' or cliometrics."[9]Fogel and North received the prize for turning the theoretical and statistical tools of modern economics on the historical past: on subjects ranging from slavery and railroads to ocean shipping and property rights. North was heralded as a pioneer in the "new" institutional history. In the Nobel announcement,[9][11]specific mention was made of a 1968 paper on ocean shipping, in which North showed that organizational changes played a greater role in increasing productivity than did technological change.[12]Fogel is especially noted for using careful empirical work to overturnconventional wisdom.

With that being said, the new economic history revolution is thought to have begun in the mid-1960s, where areas of key interest included transportation history,[13]slavery,[4]and agriculture. The discipline was resisted as many incumbent economic historians were either historians or economists who had very little connection to economic modeling or statistical techniques.[14]According to cliometric economistClaudia Goldin,the success of the cliometric revolution had as an unintended consequence the disappearance of economic historians from history departments. As economic historians started using the same tools as economists, they started to seem more like other economists. In Goldin's words, "the new economic historians extinguished the other side."[15]The other side nearly disappeared altogether, with only a few remaining in history departments and business schools. However, some new economic historians did, in fact, begin research around this time, among them were Kemmerer andLarry Neal(a student ofAlbert Fishlow,a leader of the cliometric revolution) from Illinois, Paul Uselding fromJohns Hopkins,Jeremy Atackfrom Indiana, andThomas Ulenfrom Stanford.

Cliometrics was introduced in the 1970s to Germany byRichard H. Tilly,who had been and educated in the US.[16]The Cliometric Society,a group to encourage and further the study of cliometrics, was founded in 1983.

There has been a revival in 'new economic history' since the late 1990s.[5][6]The number of papers on economic history published in the top economics journals has increased in the last decades, comprising 6.6% of articles in theAmerican Economic Reviewand 10.8% of articles in theQuarterly Journal of Economicsfor the period 2004-2014.[6]Today, cliometric approaches are standard in several journals, including theJournal of Economic History,Explorations in Economic History,theEuropean Review of Economic History,andCliometrica.

Critics[edit]

Cliometrics has had sharp critics.Francesco Boldizzonisummarized a common critique by arguing that cliometrics is based on the false assumption that the laws of neo-classical economics always apply to human activity. The considers that those laws are based onrational choiceand maximization, as they operate in well-developed markets, and do not apply to economies other than those of the capitalist West in the modern era. Instead, Boldizzoni argues that the workings of economies are determined by social, political, and cultural conditions specific to each society and time period.[17]

On the other hand, Claude Diebolt (2016) argued that cliometrics is mature and well accepted by scholars as an "indispensable tool" in economic history.[18]He believes that most scholars agree that economic theory, combined with new data as well as historical and statistical methods are necessary to formulate problems precisely, to draw conclusions from postulates and to gain insight into complex processes to close the gap betweenGeisteswissenschaftenandNaturwissenschaften:to move from the historicalverstehenor understanding side to the economicerklärenor explaining side or, much better, mi xing both approaches for the achievement of a unified approach of the social sciences. At the applied level, cliometrics is accepted to measure variables and estimate parameters.[19]

A criticism byJoseph T. Salerno,based on the perspective of theAustrian Schoolof economics, especially that ofLudwig von Mises,can be found in his Introduction toMurray N. Rothbard'sA History of Money and Banking in the United States.[20]

Distinguishing cliometrics and cliodynamics[edit]

Cliometrics andcliodynamicsshare the scientific ambition of using quantitative tools and historical data to test general historical principles. Both fields endeavor to gather large amounts of historical data across big samples. However, the two fields also differ in several ways.

Cliodynamics maintains a close relationship with the natural sciences, often employing dominant methods from the natural sciences such as differential-equation models, power-law relations, and agent-based models.Evolutionary game theoryand social network analysis are also frequently employed by cliodynamicists, but less often by cliometricians. Cliodynamicists also tend to include factors associated with ecological context and biological determinants in their models.[21]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^Fogel, Robert(December 1966). "The New Economic History. Its Findings and Methods".Economic History Review.19(3): 642–656.doi:10.1111/j.1468-0289.1966.tb00994.x.JSTOR2593168.The 'new economic history', sometimes called economic history or cliometrics, is not often practiced in Europe. However, it is fair to say that efforts to apply statistical and mathematical models currently occupy the centre of the stage in American economic history.
  2. ^Woodman, Harold (1972). "Economic History and Economic Theory: The New Economic History in America".Journal of Interdisciplinary History.3(2): 323–350.doi:10.2307/202334.JSTOR202334.Among the most recent of the changes in emphasis-today's new history-is the rise of the "new economic history" or, as it is variously called, econometric history or cliometric.
  3. ^Handbook of Cliometrics.Springer. 2016.ISBN9783642404054.Archived fromthe originalon 2019-04-16.Retrieved2015-09-30.
  4. ^abcEdward L. Glaeser,"Remembering the Father of Transportation Economics",The New York Times(Economix), October 27, 2009.
  5. ^ab"The Long Economic and Political Shadow of History, Volume 1".VoxEU.org.2017-01-23. Archived fromthe originalon 2020-01-01.Retrieved2017-03-08.
  6. ^abcAbramitzky, Ran (2015)."Economics and the Modern Economic Historian"(PDF).Journal of Economic History.75(4): 1240–1251.doi:10.1017/S0022050715001667.S2CID149483837.
  7. ^Conrad, Alfred H.; Meyer, John R. (1958). "The Economics of Slavery in the Ante Bellum South".Journal of Political Economy.66(2): 95–130.doi:10.1086/258020.JSTOR1827270.S2CID154825201.
  8. ^Goldin, Claudia(Spring 1995)."Cliometrics and the Nobel".The Journal of Economic Perspectives.9(2): 191–208 [p. 191].doi:10.1257/jep.9.2.191.JSTOR2138173.S2CID155075681.
  9. ^abcThe Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1993,Press Release,October 12, 2003.
  10. ^Diebolt, Claude; Haupert, Michael (2017-10-28)."A cliometric counterfactual: what if there had been neither Fogel nor North?"(PDF).Cliometrica.12(3): 407–434.doi:10.1007/s11698-017-0167-8.ISSN1863-2505.S2CID157074858.
  11. ^Diebolt, Claude; Haupert, Michael (2017-01-01)."A Cliometric Counterfactual: What if There Had Been Neither Fogel nor North?".{{cite journal}}:Cite journal requires|journal=(help)
  12. ^North, Douglass C. (1968). "Sources of Productivity Change in Ocean Shipping, 1600-1850".Journal of Political Economy.76(5): 953–970.doi:10.1086/259462.JSTOR1830031.S2CID153985679.
  13. ^Fogel, R. (1964).Railroads and American Economic Growth: Essays in Econometric History(1st ed.). The Johns Hopkins University Press.ISBN978-0-8018-0201-0.
  14. ^Goldin, Claudia(Spring 1995)."Cliometrics and the Nobel".The Journal of Economic Perspectives.9(2): 191–208 [p. 194].doi:10.1257/jep.9.2.191.JSTOR2138173.S2CID155075681.
  15. ^Goldin, Claudia(Spring 1995)."Cliometrics and the Nobel".The Journal of Economic Perspectives.9(2): 191–208 [p. 206].doi:10.1257/jep.9.2.191.JSTOR2138173.S2CID155075681.
  16. ^"Verleihung des Helmut-Schmidt-Preises 2009 an Richard Hugh Tilly".Archived fromthe originalon 2013-10-29.Retrieved2013-06-22.
  17. ^Boldizzoni, Francesco (2011).The Poverty of Clio: Resurrecting Economic History.Princeton University Press.ISBN9780691144009.
  18. ^Diebolt, Claude (2016)."Cliometrica after 10 years: definition and principles of cliometric research".Cliometrica.10:1–4.doi:10.1007/s11698-015-0136-z.
  19. ^Diebolt, Claude (2012). "Where Are We Now in Cliometrics? Kliometrie: wo stehen wir heute?".Historical Social Research.37(4): 309–326.
  20. ^Rothbard, Murray (2002).A History of Money and Banking in the United States: The Colonial Era to World War II.Ludwig von Mises Institute.ISBN978-0945466338.
  21. ^Mejía, Javier (2015)."The Evolution of Economic History since 1950: From Cliometrics to Cliodynamics".Tiempo & Economia.2(2): 79–103.doi:10.21789/24222704.1061.hdl:20.500.12010/733.SSRN2708321.

Further reading[edit]

External links[edit]