Jump to content

First-past-the-post voting

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected fromFirst past the post)


Countries that primarily use a first-past-the-post voting system for national legislative elections

First-preference plurality(FPP)—often shortened simply toplurality—is asingle-winnersystem ofpositional votingwhere voters mark one candidate as their favorite, and the candidate with the largest number of points (apluralityof points) is elected. It is also calledfirst-past-the-post(FPTP), based on a metaphor fromhorse racing.[1][2]

Insocial choice theory,FPP is considered adegenerateform ofranked voting,where voters "rank" candidates, but only the first preference matters; as a result, FPP is usually implemented using achoose-one ballot,where voters mark a single bubble next to their favorite candidate.

FPP has been used to elect theBritish House of Commonssince theMiddle Ages.Its use extends to former British colonies, most notably theUnited States,Canada,andIndia.It is used as the primary form of allocating seats for legislative elections in about a third of the world's countries, mostly in theEnglish-speaking world.It is also used to directly elect heads of states in some, although less often than thetwo-round system.[citation needed]

Notwithstanding its simplicity and antiquity, there are several major drawbacks to FPTP. As awinner-take-allmethod, it often produces disproportional results, particularly when electing members of a legislature, in the sense that political parties do not get representation according to their share of the popular vote. This usually favors the largest party and parties with strong regional support to the detriment of smaller parties without a geographically concentratedbase.

Supporters ofelectoral reformare generally highly critical of FPTP because of this and point out other flaws, such as FPTP's vulnerability togerrymanderingwhich can create districts distorting representation in the legislature, the high number ofwasted votes,and the chance of a majority reversal (i.e., the party winning the most votes getting fewer seats than the second-largest party and losing the election). Throughout the 20th century many countries that previously used FPTP have abandoned it in favour of other electoral systems, including the former British coloniesAustralia,andNew Zealand(these nations now useIRV+STVandMMP,respectively).

Some countries use FPTP alongsideproportional representation(PR) in aparallel votingsystem, or in compensatory mixed systems, e.g. as part ofmixed-member proportional representation.

Description[edit]

A first-past-the-post ballot for a single-member district. The voter must mark one (andonly one).

A first-past-the-post election entails a single winner. The ballot requires voters to mark only one option from the list of candidates. Whichever candidate wins the greatest number, orplurality,of votes wins. In a legislative election, the polity is divided into any number of districts, or constituencies, each of which elect a representative to the legislature via FPTP.

Example[edit]

Tennessee and its four major cities: Memphis in the far west; Nashville in the center; Chattanooga in the east; and Knoxville in the far northeast

Suppose thatTennesseeis holding an election on the location of itscapital.The population is concentrated around four major cities.All voters want the capital to be as close to them as possible.The options are:

  • Memphis,the largest city, but far from the others (42% of voters)
  • Nashville,near the center of the state (26% of voters)
  • Chattanooga,somewhat east (15% of voters)
  • Knoxville,far to the northeast (17% of voters)

The preferences of each region's voters are:

42% of voters
Far-West
26% of voters
Center
15% of voters
Center-East
17% of voters
Far-East
  1. Memphis
  2. Nashville
  3. Chattanooga
  4. Knoxville
  1. Nashville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Knoxville
  4. Memphis
  1. Chattanooga
  2. Knoxville
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis
  1. Knoxville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis


In FPTP, only the first preferences matter. Voters are allowed to make only one choice of candidate. As such, the votes would be counted as 42 per cent for Memphis, 26 for Nashville, 17 for Knoxville, and 15 for Chattanooga. Since Memphis has the most votes, it would win a FPTP election, even though a majority of voters prefer Nashville. This makes the election acenter squeeze.By contrast,Condorcet methodswouldreturn Nashville– the actual capital of Tennessee – whereasinstant-runoff votingwouldreturn Knoxville,the easternmost city.

Voting method criteria[edit]

Scholars rate voting methods using mathematically derivedvoting method criteria,which describe desirable features of a method. The following criteria are passed or failed when FPTP is used in a single-winner contest:

Name of criterion Explanation/details
checkY Majority criterion Themajority criterionstates that "if one candidate is ranked in first place by a majority (more than 50%) of voters, then that candidate must win."[3]First-past-the-post meets this criterion (though not the converse: a candidate does not need 50% of the votes in order to win)
☒N Mutual majority criterion Themutual majority criterionstates that "if a majority (more than 50%) of voters top-rank some k candidates, then one of those k candidates must win". First-past-the-post does not meet this criterion.[4]
☒N Condorcet winner criterion TheCondorcet winnercriterion states that "if a candidate would get a majority of the vote in a head-to-head competition no matter who they would be facing, they must win." First-past-the-post does not[5]meet this criterion.
☒N Condorcet loser criterion TheCondorcet losercriterion states that "if a candidate would lose ahead-to-head competitionagainst every other candidate, then that candidate must not win the overall election ". First-past-the-post does not[5]meet this criterion.
☒N Independence of irrelevant alternatives criterion Theindependence of irrelevant alternativescriterion states that "the election outcome remains the same even if a candidate who cannot win decides to run." First-past-the-post does not meet this criterion. This makes it vulnerable tospoilers.
☒N Independence of clones criterion Theindependence of clones criterionsays that the election outcome remains the same, even if multiple copies or "clones" of a candidate run. Candidate-cloning causes vote-splitting in FPP.
checkY Monotonicity criterion The monotonicity criterion says a candidate should not lose as a result of receiving "too much support" from some voters, i.e. increasing a candidate's ranking can't make them lose. FPP satisfies this.
checkY Consistency criterion
checkY Participation criterion
☒N Reversal symmetry Reversal symmetry is a voting system criterion which requires that if candidate A is the unique winner, and each voter's individual preferences are inverted, then A must not be elected
checkY Later-no-harm Since plurality does consider later preferences on the ballot at all, it is impossible to either harm or help a favorite candidate by marking later preferences, and so it passes both Later-No-Harm and Later-No-Help.
checkY Later-no-help

Terminology[edit]

The phrasefirst-past-the-postis a metaphor from Britishhorse racing,where there is a post at the finish line.[6]While widely-used, the term is amisnomerin that it is precisely backwards: there is no specific percentage "finish line" required to win in a plurality voting system, and any candidate can win.

FPTP is aplurality votingmethod, apluralitymeaning the largest part of the whole, in contrast tomajority,which generally means more than half of the whole. Under FPTP the candidate with the highest number (but not necessarily a majority) of votes is elected. Sometimes the termrelative majorityis used to refer to a plurality as opposed to anabsolute majoritymeaning a (standard) majority.

Even though FPTP is a type of plurality voting, it is categorised as amajoritarian system,even though it does not always elect themajority-preferred candidate.FPTP is primarily used in systems that usesingle-member electoral divisions.The multiple-member version of plurality voting is when each voter casts (up to) the same number of votes as there are positions to be filled, and those elected are the highest-placed candidates; this system is calledblock plurality voting.When voters have only a single vote each, which is non-transferable, but there are multiple seats to be filled, that system is called thesingle non-transferable vote(SNTV), which is a

Effects[edit]

Party distribution[edit]

A graph showing the difference between the popular vote (inner circle) and the seats won by parties (outer circle) at the2015 UK general election

Perhaps the most striking effect of FPTP is the fact that the number of a party's seats in a legislature has nothing to do with its vote count in an election, only in how those votes were geographically distributed. This has been a target of criticism for the method, many arguing that a fundamental requirement of an election system is to accurately represent the views of voters. FPTP often creates "false majorities" by over-representing larger parties (giving a majority of the parliamentary/legislative seats to a party that did not receive a majority of the votes) while under-representing smaller ones. In Canada,majority governmentshave been formed due to one party winning a majority of the votes cast in Canada only three times since 1921: in1940,1958and1984.In the United Kingdom, 19 of the 24 general elections since 1922 have produced a single-party majority government. In all but two of them (1931and1935), the leading party did not take a majority of the votes across the UK.

In extreme cases, this can lead to a party receiving the plurality or even majority of total votes yet still failing to gain a plurality of legislative seats. This results in a situation called amajority reversalorelectoral inversion.[7][8]Famous examples of the second placed party (in votes nationally) winning a majority of seats include the elections in Ghana in2012,in New Zealand in1978and1981,and in the United Kingdom in1951.Famous examples of the second placed party (in votes nationally) winning a plurality of seats include the elections in Canada in2019and2021as well as in Japan in2003.Even when a party wins more than half the votes in an almost purely two-party-competition, it is possible for the runner-up to win a majority of seats. This happened in Saint Vincent and the Grenadines in1966,1998and2020and in Belize in1993.Even with only two parties and equally-sized constituencies, winning a majority of seats just requires receiving more than half the vote in more than half the districts—even if the other party receives all the votes cast in the other districts—so just over a quarter of the vote is theoretically enough to win a majority in the legislature. With enough candidates splitting the vote in a district, the total number of votes needed to win can be madearbitrarily small.

Under first-past-the-post, a small party may draw votes and seats away from a larger party that it ismoresimilar to, and therefore give an advantage to one it islesssimilar to. For example, in the2000 United States presidential election,the left-leaningRalph Naderdrew more votes from the left-leaningAl Gore,resulting in Naderspoiling the electionfor the Democrats. According to the political pressure groupMake Votes Matter,FPTP creates a powerful electoral incentive for large parties to target similar segments of voters with similar policies. The effect of this reduces political diversity in a country because the larger parties are incentivised to coalesce around similar policies.[9]TheACE Electoral Knowledge Networkdescribes India's use of FPTP as a "legacy of British colonialism".[10]

Duverger's lawis an idea inpolitical sciencewhich says that constituencies that use first-past-the-post methods will lead totwo-party systems,given enough time. EconomistJeffrey Sachsexplains:

The main reason for America's majoritarian character is the electoral system for Congress. Members of Congress are elected in single-member districts according to the "first-past-the-post" (FPTP) principle, meaning that the candidate with the plurality of votes is the winner of the congressional seat. The losing party or parties win no representation at all. The first-past-the-post election tends to produce a small number of major parties, perhaps just two, a principle known in political science asDuverger's Law.Smaller parties are trampled in first-past-the-post elections.

— from Sachs'sThe Price of Civilization,2011[11]

However, most countries with first-past-the-post elections have multiparty legislatures (albeit with two parties larger than the others), the United States being the major exception.[12]There is a counter-argument to Duverger's Law, that while on the national level a plurality system may encourage two parties, in the individual constituencies supermajorities will lead to the vote fracturing.[13]

It has been suggested that the distortions in geographical representation provide incentives for parties to ignore the interests of areas in which they are too weak to stand much chance of gaining representation, leading to governments that do not govern in the national interest. Further, during election campaigns the campaigning activity of parties tends to focus onmarginal seatswhere there is a prospect of a change in representation, leaving safer areas excluded from participation in an active campaign.[14]Political parties operate by targeting districts, directing their activists and policy proposals toward those areas considered to be marginal, where each additional vote has more value.[15][16][17]

This feature of FPTP has often been used by its supporters in contrast to proportional systems. In the latter, smaller parties act as 'kingmakers' in coalitions as they have greater bargaining power and therefore, arguably, their influence on policy is disproportional to their parliamentary size- this is largely avoided in FPTP systems where majorities are generally achieved.[18]FPTP often produces governments which have legislative voting majorities,[19]thus providing such governments the legislative power necessary to implement their electoralmanifestocommitments during their term in office. This may be beneficial for the country in question in circumstances where the government's legislative agenda has broad public support, albeit potentially divided across party lines, or at least benefits society as a whole. However handing a legislative voting majority to a government which lacks popular support can be problematic where said government's policies favour only that fraction of the electorate that supported it, particularly if the electorate divides on tribal, religious, or urban–rural lines. There is also the perceived issue of unfair coalitions where a smaller party can form a coalition with other smaller parties and form a government, without a clear mandate as was the case in the2009 Israeli legislative electionwhere the leading partyKadima,was unable to form a coalition soLikud,a smaller party, managed to form a government without being the largest party. The use ofproportional representation(PR) may enable smaller parties to become decisive in the country'slegislatureand gain leverage they would not otherwise enjoy, although this can be somewhat mitigated by a large enoughelectoral threshold.They argue that FPTP generally reduces this possibility, except where parties have a strong regional basis. A journalist atHaaretznoted that Israel's highly proportionalKnesset"affords great power to relatively small parties, forcing the government to give in to political blackmail and to reach compromises";[20][21]Tony Blair,defending FPTP, argued that other systems give small parties the balance of power, and influence disproportionate to their votes.[22]Allowing people into parliament who did not finish first in their district was described byDavid Cameronas creating a "Parliament full of second-choices who no one really wanted but didn't really object to either."[23]Winston Churchillcriticized the alternative vote system as "determined by the most worthless votes given for the most worthless candidates."[24]

FPTP often results instrategic votingwhich has prevented extreme left and right-wing parties from gaining parliamentary seats. For example, PR systems such as theelectoral system of Hungaryhave seen Fidesz (right-wing, populist party) win 135 seats in the2022 Hungarian parliamentary electionand has remained the largest party in Hungary since2010.Since 2010, Fidesz has implemented anti-democratic reforms that now mean the European Parliament no longer qualifies Hungary as a full democracy.[25]On the other hand,the Constitution Societypublished a report in April 2019 stating that, "[in certain circumstances] FPTP can... abetextreme politics,since should a radical faction gain control of one of the major political parties, FPTP works to preserve that party's position....This is because the psychological effect of the plurality system disincentivises a major party's supporters from voting for a minor party in protest at its policies, since to do so would likely only help the major party's main rival. Rather than curtailing extreme voices, FPTP today empowers the (relatively) extreme voices of the Labour and Conservative party memberships. "[26][27]Electoral reform campaigners have argued that the use of FPTP inSouth Africawas a contributory factor in the country adopting theapartheidsystem after the1948 general electionin that country.[28][29]Leblang and Chan found that a country's electoral system is the most important predictor of a country's involvement in war, according to three different measures: (1) when a country was the first to enter a war; (2) when it joined a multinational coalition in an ongoing war; and (3) how long it stayed in a war after becoming a party to it.[30][31]When the people are fairly represented in parliament, more of those groups who may object to any potential war have access to the political power necessary to prevent it. In a proportional democracy, war and other major decisions generally requires the consent of the majority.[31][32][33]The British human rights campaignerPeter Tatchell,and others, have argued that Britain entered the Iraq War primarily because of the political effects of FPTP and that proportional representation would have prevented Britain's involvement in the war.[34][35][36]

Tactical voting[edit]

To a greater extent than many others, the first-past-the-post method encourages "tactical voting". Voters have an incentive to vote for a candidate who they predict is more likely to win, as opposed to their preferred candidate who may be unlikely to win and for whom a vote could be considered aswasted.FPTP wastes fewer votes when it is used in two-party contests. But waste of votes and minority governments are more likely when large groups of voters vote for three, four or more parties as in Canadian elections. Canada uses FPTP and only two of the last seven federal Canadian elections (2011and2015) produced single-party majority governments. In none of them did the leading party receive a majority of the votes.

The position is sometimes summarised, in an extreme form, as "all votes for anyone other than the runner-up are votes for the winner."[37]This is because votes for these other candidates deny potential support from the second-placed candidate, who might otherwise have won. Following the extremely close2000 U.S. presidential election,some supporters ofDemocraticcandidateAl Gorebelieved one reason he lost toRepublicanGeorge W. Bushis that a portion of the electorate (2.7%) voted forRalph Naderof theGreen Party,and exit polls indicated that more of them would have preferred Gore (45%) to Bush (27%).[38]This election was ultimately determined by theresults from Florida,where Bush prevailed over Gore by a margin of only 537 votes (0.009%), which was far exceeded by the 97488 (1.635%) votes cast for Nader in that state.

InPuerto Rico,there has been a tendency forIndependentistavoters to supportPopularescandidates. This phenomenon is responsible for some Popular victories, even though theEstadistashave the most voters on the island, and is so widely recognised that Puerto Ricans sometimes call the Independentistas who vote for the Populares "melons", because that fruit is green on the outside but red on the inside (in reference to the party colors).

Because voters have to predict who the top two candidates will be, results can be significantly distorted:

  • Some voters will vote based on their view of how others will vote as well, changing their originally intended vote;
  • Substantial power is given to the media, because some voters will believe its assertions as to who the leading contenders are likely to be. Even voters who distrust the media will know that othersdobelieve the media, and therefore those candidates who receive the most media attention will probably be the most popular;
  • A new candidate with no track record, who might otherwise be supported by the majority of voters, may be considered unlikely to be one of the top two, and thus lose votes to tactical voting;
  • The method may promote votesagainstas opposed to votesfor.For example, in the UK (and only in theGreat Britainregion), entire campaigns have been organised with the aim of votingagainsttheConservative Partyby votingLabour,Liberal DemocratinEnglandandWales,and since 2015 theSNPinScotland,depending on which is seen as best placed to win in each locality. Such behaviour is difficult to measure objectively.

Proponents of other voting methods insingle-member districtsargue that these would reduce the need for tactical voting and reduce thespoiler effect.Examples include preferential voting systems, such asinstant runoff voting,as well as thetwo-round systemof runoffs and less tested methods such asapproval votingandCondorcet methods. Wasted votesare seen as those cast for losing candidates, and for winning candidates in excess of the number required for victory. For example, in theUK general election of 2005,52% of votes were cast for losing candidates and 18% were excess votes—a total of 70% "wasted" votes. On this basis a large majority of votes may play no part in determining the outcome. This winner-takes-all system may be one of the reasons why "voter participation tends to be lower in countries with FPTP than elsewhere."[39]

Geography[edit]

The effect of a system based on plurality voting spread over many separate districts is that the larger parties, and parties with more geographically concentrated support, gain a disproportionately large share of seats, while smaller parties with more evenly distributed support gain a disproportionately small share. This is because in doing this they win many seats and do not 'waste' many votes in other areas. As voting patterns are similar in about two-thirds of the districts, it is more likely that a single party will hold a majority of legislative seats under FPTP than happens in a proportional system, and under FPTP it is rare to elect a majority government that actually has the support of a majority of voters. Because FPTP permits manywasted votes,an election under FPTP is more easily gerrymandered. Throughgerrymandering,electoral areas are designed deliberately to unfairly increase the number of seats won by one party by redrawing the map such that one party has a small number of districts in which it has an overwhelming majority of votes (whether due to policy, demographics which tend to favour one party, or other reasons), and many districts where it is at a smaller disadvantage.[citation needed]

The BritishElectoral Reform Society(ERS) says that regional parties benefit from this system. "With a geographical base, parties that are small UK-wide can still do very well".[40]

On the other hand, minor parties that do not concentrate their vote usually end up getting a much lower proportion of seats than votes, as they lose most of the seats they contest and 'waste' most of their votes.[17]

The ERS also says that in FPTP elections using many separate districts "small parties without a geographical base find it hard to win seats".[40]

Make Votes Mattersaid that in the2017 general election,"the Green Party, Liberal Democrats and UKIP (minor, non-regional parties) received 11% of votes between them, yet theysharedjust 2% of seats ", and in the2015 general election,"[t]he same three parties received almost a quarter of all the votes cast, yet these partiessharedjust 1.5% of seats. "[41]

According to Make Votes Matter, in the 2015 UK general electionUKIPcame in third in terms of number of votes (3.9 million/12.6%), but gained only one seat in Parliament, resulting in one seat per 3.9 million votes. The Conservatives on the other hand received one seat per 34,000 votes.[41]

The winner-takes-all nature of FPTP leads to distorted patterns of representation, since it exaggerates the correlation between party support and geography.

For example, in the UK theConservative Partyrepresents most of the rural seats in England, and most of the south of England, while theLabour Partyrepresents most of the English cities and most of the north of England.[42]This pattern hides the large number of votes for the non-dominant party. Parties can find themselves without elected politicians in significant parts of the country, heightening feelings of regionalism. Party supporters (who may nevertheless be a significant minority) in those sections of the country are unrepresented.

In the 2019 Canadian federal electionConservativeswon 98% of the seats in Alberta and Saskatchewan with only 68% of the vote. The lack of non-Conservative representation gives the appearance of greater Conservative support than actually exists.[43]Similarly, in Canada's 2021 elections, the Conservative Party won 88% of the seats in Alberta with only 55% of the vote, and won 100% of the seats in Saskatchewan with only 59% of the vote.[44]

First-past-the-post within geographical areas tends to deliver (particularly to larger parties) a significant number ofsafe seats,where a representative is sheltered from any but the most dramatic change in voting behaviour. In the UK, the Electoral Reform Society estimates that more than half the seats can be considered as safe.[45]It has been claimed that members involved in the 2009expenses scandalwere significantly more likely to hold a safe seat.[46][47]

History[edit]

FPTP is one of the simplest electoral systems, and alongside block voting has been used since ancient times. TheHouse of Commons of Englandoriginated in the Middle Ages as an assembly representing the gentry of the counties and cities of the Kingdom, each of which generally sent two members of parliament (MPs). These two MPs were elected by block voting, although theby-electionsthat occurred between general elections were elected by FPTP. Starting in the 19th century and concluding with theRepresentation of the People Act 1948,constituencies to the House of Commons were all reduced to electing one MP each by FPTP.

TheUnited Statesbroke away from British rule in the late 18th century, and its constitution provides for an electoral college to elect its president. Despite original intentions to the contrary, by the mid-19th century this college had transformed into ade factouse of FPTP by the states' presidential elections. In any event, direct elections to theUnited States House of Representativeswere conducted in FPTP, as were elections to theUnited States Senateboth in the state legislatures and after they were made directly to the people. InCanada,elections to theHouse of Commons,and to provincial assemblies, have always been conducted with FPTP.

Criticism and replacement[edit]

People campaigning against first-past-the-post and in favour of proportional representation

Non-plurality voting systems have been devised since at least 1299, whenRamon Llullcame up with both the Condorcet andBorda countmethods, which were respectively reinvented in the 18th century by theMarquis de CondorcetandJean-Charles de Borda.More serious investigation into electoral systems came in the late 18th century, when several thinkers independently proposed systems ofproportional representationto elect legislatures. Thesingle transferable votein particular was invented in 1819 byThomas Wright Hill,and first used in a public election in 1840 by his sonRowlandfor theAdelaide City Councilin Australia. STV saw its first national use in Denmark in 1855, and was reinvented several times in the late 19th century.

The Proportional Representation Society was founded in England in 1884 and began campaigning. STV was used to elect the British House of Commons'suniversity constituenciesbetween 1918 and their abolition in 1950.

Many countries which use FPTP have active campaigns to switch to proportional representation (e.g. UK[48]and Canada[49]). Most modern democracies use some form of proportional representation.[50]In the case of the UK, the campaign to get rid of FPTP has been ongoing since at least the 1970s.[51]However, in both these countries, reform campaigners face the obstacle of large incumbent parties who control the legislature and who are incentivised to resist any attempts to replace the FPTP system that elected them on a minority vote.

Countries using FPTP/SMP[edit]

Heads of state elected by FPTP[edit]

Legislatures elected exclusively by FPTP/SMP[edit]

The following is a list of countries currently following the first-past-the-post voting system for their national legislatures.[52][53]

Map showing countries where the lower house or unicameral national legislature is elected by FPTP (red) or mixed systems using FPTP (pink - mixed majoritarian, purple/lavender - mixed proportional/compensatory).

Use of FPTP/SMP in mixed systems for electing legislatures[edit]

The following countries use FPTP/SMP to elect part of their national legislature, in different types of mixed systems.

Alongside block voting (fully majoritarian systems) or as part of mixed-member majoritarian systems (semi-proportional representation)

As part of mixed-member proportional (MMP) or additional member systems (AMS)

Subnational legislatures

Local elections

Former use[edit]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^"First past the post".nzhistory.govt.nz.Ministry for Culture and Heritage.13 January 2016.Archivedfrom the original on 24 May 2022.Retrieved25 May2022.
  2. ^"First Past the Post and Alternative Vote explained".gov.uk.6 September 2010.Archivedfrom the original on 18 January 2024.Retrieved13 July2024.
  3. ^"Single-winner Voting Method Comparison Chart".FairVote.27 February 2011. Archived fromthe originalon 28 February 2011."Majority Favorite Criterion: If a majority (more than 50%) of voters consider candidate A to be the best choice, then A should win."
  4. ^Kondratev, Aleksei Y.; Nesterov, Alexander S. (2020). "Measuring Majority Power and Veto Power of Voting Rules".Public Choice.183(1–2): 187–210.arXiv:1811.06739.doi:10.1007/s11127-019-00697-1.S2CID53670198.
  5. ^abFelsenthal, Dan S. (2010)Review of paradoxes afflicting various voting procedures where one out of m candidates (m ≥ 2) must be electedArchived24 February 2021 at theWayback Machine.In: Assessing Alternative Voting Procedures, London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK.
  6. ^Tréguer, Pascal (11 May 2019)."origin of 'first past the post' (as applied to a voting system)".Archivedfrom the original on 27 January 2022.Retrieved10 July2021.
  7. ^Geruso, Michael; Spears, Dean; Talesara, Ishaana (5 September 2019)."Inversions in US Presidential Elections: 1836-2016".American Economic Journal: Applied Economics.14(1): 327–357.doi:10.3386/w26247.Archivedfrom the original on 19 March 2021.Retrieved14 July2021.
  8. ^Miller, Nicholas R."Election Inversions By Variants of the U.S. Electoral College".Department of Political Science. UMBC. Archived fromthe originalon 18 July 2021.Retrieved14 July2021.
  9. ^"First Past the Post".Make Votes Matter.Archivedfrom the original on 31 July 2020.Retrieved26 June2020.
  10. ^"India – First Past the Post on a Grand Scale".ACE Electoral Knowledge Network.Retrieved25 June2020.
  11. ^Sachs, Jeffrey (2011).The Price of Civilization.New York: Random House. p. 107.ISBN978-1-4000-6841-8.
  12. ^Dunleavy, Patrick; Diwakar, Rekha (2013)."Analysing multiparty competition in plurality rule elections"(PDF).Party Politics.19(6): 855–886.doi:10.1177/1354068811411026.S2CID18840573.Archived(PDF)from the original on 9 June 2022.Retrieved30 June2016.
  13. ^Dickson, Eric S.;Scheve, Kenneth(2010). "Social Identity, Electoral Institutions and the Number of Candidates".British Journal of Political Science.40(2): 349–375.CiteSeerX10.1.1.75.155.doi:10.1017/s0007123409990354.JSTOR40649446.S2CID7107526.
  14. ^"First Past the Post is a 'broken voting system'".ippr.org.Institute for Public Policy Research. 4 January 2011.Archivedfrom the original on 15 November 2017.Retrieved15 November2017.
  15. ^Terry, Chris (28 August 2013)."In Britain's first past the post electoral system, some votes are worth 22 times more than others".democraticaudit.London School of Economics.Retrieved15 November2017.
  16. ^Galvin, Ray."What is a marginal seat?".justsolutions.eu.Archivedfrom the original on 15 November 2017.Retrieved15 November2017.
  17. ^ab"First Past the Post".electoral-reform.org.uk.Archivedfrom the original on 13 December 2019.Retrieved5 December2019.
  18. ^Brams/Kilgour. Dorey (2013)."Kingmakers and leaders in coalition formation".Social Choice and Welfare.41(1): 1–18.doi:10.1007/s00355-012-0680-4.hdl:10419/53209.JSTOR42001390.S2CID253849669.Archivedfrom the original on 11 March 2023.Retrieved11 March2023.
  19. ^Andy Williams (1998).UK Government & Politics.Heinemann. p. 24.ISBN978-0-435-33158-0.Archivedfrom the original on 22 May 2024.Retrieved11 October2016.
  20. ^Ilan, Shahar."Major Reforms Are Unlikely, but Electoral Threshold Could Be Raised".Haaretz.Archivedfrom the original on 21 August 2019.Retrieved8 May2010.
  21. ^Dr.Mihaela Macavei, University of Alba Iulia, Romania."Advantages and disadvantages of the uninominal voting system"(PDF).Archived fromthe original(PDF)on 24 December 2019.Retrieved8 May2010.{{cite web}}:CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  22. ^P. Dorey (17 June 2008).The Labour Party and Constitutional Reform: A History of Constitutional Conservatism.Palgrave Macmillan UK. pp. 400–.ISBN978-0-230-59415-9.
  23. ^"David Cameron."David Cameron: why keeping first past the post is vital for democracyArchived18 January 2018 at theWayback Machine."Daily Telegraph.30 April 2011
  24. ^Larry Johnston (13 December 2011).Politics: An Introduction to the Modern Democratic State.University of Toronto Press. pp. 231–.ISBN978-1-4426-0533-6.
  25. ^"MEPs: Hungary can no longer be considered a full democracy"(Press release).European Parliament.15 September 2022.Archivedfrom the original on 15 September 2022.Retrieved25 March2023.
  26. ^Walker, Peter (22 April 2019)."First past the post abets extreme politics, says thinktank".The Guardian.Archivedfrom the original on 6 December 2023.Retrieved23 June2020.
  27. ^"The Electoral System and British Politics".consoc.org.uk.Archivedfrom the original on 25 June 2020.Retrieved23 June2020.
  28. ^Cowen, Doug."The Graveyard of First Past the Post".Electoral Reform Society.Archivedfrom the original on 4 July 2020.Retrieved4 July2020.
  29. ^Winter, Owen (25 August 2016)."How a Broken Voting System Gave South Africa Apartheid in 1948".Huffington Post.Archivedfrom the original on 18 March 2021.Retrieved4 July2020.
  30. ^Leblang, D.; Chan, S. (2003). "Explaining Wars Fought By Established Democracies: Do Institutional Constraints Matter?".Political Research Quarterly:56-24: 385–400.
  31. ^ab"PR and Conflict".Make Votes Matter.Archivedfrom the original on 31 July 2020.Retrieved27 June2020.
  32. ^"What the Evidence Says".Fair Voting BC.19 November 2017.Archivedfrom the original on 29 June 2020.Retrieved27 June2020.
  33. ^"Democracy: we've never had it so bad".The Guardian.3 May 2010.Archivedfrom the original on 22 May 2024.Retrieved27 June2020.
  34. ^Tatchell, Peter (3 May 2010)."Democracy: we've never had it so bad".The Guardian.Archivedfrom the original on 22 May 2024.Retrieved26 June2020.
  35. ^Barnett, Anthony (10 January 2020)."Will Labour's next leader finally break with first-past-the-post?".Labourlist.org.Archivedfrom the original on 5 July 2020.Retrieved5 July2020.
  36. ^Root, Tim (30 September 2019)."Making government accountable to the people".Left Foot Forward.Archivedfrom the original on 31 July 2020.Retrieved5 July2020.
  37. ^Begany, Brent (30 June 2016)."The 2016 Election Proves The Need For Voting Reform".Policy Interns.Archivedfrom the original on 22 October 2019.Retrieved22 October2019.
  38. ^Rosenbaum, David E. (24 February 2004)."THE 2004 CAMPAIGN: THE INDEPENDENT; Relax, Nader Advises Alarmed Democrats, but the 2000 Math Counsels Otherwise".The New York Times.Archivedfrom the original on 19 September 2008.Retrieved7 February2017.
  39. ^Drogus, Carol Ann (2008).Introducing comparative politics: concepts and cases in context.CQ Press. pp.257.ISBN978-0-87289-343-6.
  40. ^ab"First Past the Post".electoral-reform.org.uk.Archivedfrom the original on 13 December 2019.Retrieved16 December2019.
  41. ^ab"Make Votes Matter—Everything wrong with First Past the Post—Proportional Representation".Make Votes Matter.Archivedfrom the original on 2 November 2019.Retrieved16 December2019.
  42. ^Beech, Matt; Hickson, Kevin (3 July 2020)."Divided by Values: Jeremy Corbyn, the Labour Party and England's 'North-South Divide'".Revue Française de Civilisation Britannique.XXV(2).doi:10.4000/rfcb.5456.S2CID198655613.
  43. ^"First Past the Post".conservativeelectoralreform.org.Conservative Action for Electoral Reform. Archived fromthe originalon 15 November 2017.Retrieved15 November2017.
  44. ^"Elections Canada – Results by Province(s)".2021 Elections Canada – Provinces.Elections Canada. 21 September 2020.Archivedfrom the original on 9 December 2022.Retrieved4 November2021.
  45. ^"General Election 2010: Safe and marginal seats".The Guardian.7 April 2010.Archivedfrom the original on 3 March 2016.Retrieved15 November2017.
  46. ^Wickham, Alex.""Safe seats" almost guarantee corruption ".thecommentator.Archived fromthe originalon 15 April 2021.Retrieved15 November2017.
  47. ^"FactCheck: expenses and safe seats".channel4.Channel 4.Archivedfrom the original on 8 May 2021.Retrieved15 November2017.
  48. ^"What We Stand For".electoral-reform.org.uk.Archivedfrom the original on 26 June 2020.Retrieved25 June2020.
  49. ^"Home".Fair Vote Canada.Archivedfrom the original on 1 July 2020.Retrieved25 June2020.
  50. ^"Electoral Systems around the World".FairVote.org.Archived fromthe originalon 11 September 2021.Retrieved18 July2020.
  51. ^"Labour Campaign for Electoral Reform – About LCER".labourcampaignforelectoralreform.org.uk.Archived fromthe originalon 11 August 2021.Retrieved25 June2020.
  52. ^"Countries using FPTP electoral system for national legislature".idea.int.Archived fromthe originalon 6 October 2014.Retrieved3 December2018.
  53. ^"Electoral Systems".ACE Electoral Knowledge Network. Archived fromthe originalon 26 August 2014.Retrieved3 November2015.
  54. ^"Electoral College Frequently Asked Questions".National Archives.6 July 2023.Archivedfrom the original on 6 December 2023.Retrieved23 October2015.
  55. ^Milia, Juan Guillermo (2015).El Voto. Expresión del poder ciudadano.Buenos Aires: Editorial Dunken. pp. 40–41.ISBN978-987-02-8472-7.[permanent dead link]
  56. ^"Law 14,032".Sistema Argentino de Información Jurídica.Archivedfrom the original on 20 October 2017.Retrieved19 October2017.
  57. ^"Kiesstelsel. §1.1 Federale verkiezingen".Encarta-encyclopedie Winkler Prins.Microsoft Corporation/Het Spectrum. 1993–2002.
  58. ^"Elections 2019: The European Parliament".Flanders News.17 April 2019.Archivedfrom the original on 6 April 2023.Retrieved2 December2022.The European Parliament elections in Belgium will be held on 26 May, the same day as the regional and federal elections. In the European elections there are three Belgian constituencies: the Dutch-speaking electoral college, the Francophone electoral college and the German-speaking electoral college.
  59. ^Bhuwan Chandra Upreti (2010).Nepal: Transition to Democratic Republican State: 2008 Constituent Assembly.Gyan Publishing House. pp. 69–.ISBN978-81-7835-774-4.Archivedfrom the original on 22 May 2024.Retrieved11 October2016.
  60. ^Encarta-encyclopedie Winkler Prins (1993–2002) s.v. "Kiesstelsel. §1.1 Geschiedenis". Microsoft Corporation/Het Spectrum.
  61. ^"PNG voting system praised by new MP".Australian Broadcasting Corporation.12 December 2003. Archived fromthe originalon 4 January 2005.Retrieved19 May2015.
  62. ^"Which European countries use proportional representation?".electoral-reform.org.uk.Archivedfrom the original on 27 December 2019.Retrieved1 December2019.
  63. ^MrdaljPolitikolog, Mladen; Univerzitetu, Predavač na Webster (8 October 2020)."Sedam zabluda o uvođenju većinskog izbornog sistema".Talas.rs.Archivedfrom the original on 13 January 2024.Retrieved13 January2024.
  1. ^Prior to the2020 election,the US states ofAlaskaandMainecompletely abandoned FPTP in favor ofInstant-runoff votingor IRV. In the US, 48 of the 50statesand theDistrict of Columbiause FPTP-GTto choose the electors of theElectoral College(which in turn elects the president); Maine andNebraskause a variation where the electoral vote of each congressional district is awarded by FPTP (or by IRV in Maine beginning in 2020), and the statewide winner (using the same method used in each congressional district in the state) is awarded an additional two electoral votes. In states that employ FPTP-GT, the presidential candidate gaining the greatest number of votes wins all the state's available electors (seats), regardless of the number or share of votes won (majority vs non-majority plurality), or the difference separating the leading candidate and the first runner-up.[54]

External links[edit]