Jump to content

Kharaj

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Kharāj(Arabic:خراج) is a type of individualIslamic taxonagricultural landand itsproduce,regardless of the religion of the owners, developed underIslamic law.[1]

With thefirst Muslim conquestsin the 7th century, thekharajinitially was synonymous withjizyahand denoted a lump-sum duty levied upon the lands of conquered provinces, which was collected by hold-over officials of the defeatedByzantine Empirein the west and theSassanid Empirein the east; later and more broadly,kharajrefers to a land-tax levied by Muslim rulers on their non-Muslim subjects, collectively known asdhimmi.Muslim landowners, on the other hand, paidushr,a religioustitheon land, which carried a lower rate of taxation,[2]andzakat.Ushrwas a reciprocal 10% levy on agricultural land as well as merchandise imported from states that taxed Muslims on their products.

Changes soon eroded the established tax base of the earlyArab Caliphates.Additionally, alarge, but unsuccessful, expeditionagainst the Byzantine Empire undertaken by theUmayyadcaliphSulaymanin 717 brought the finances of the Umayyads to the brink of collapse. Even before Sulayman's ascent to power, the powerful governor of Iraq,al-Hajjaj ibn Yusuf,attempted to raise revenues by demanding from Muslims a full rate of taxation, but that measure met with opposition and resentment. To address these problems, Sulayman's successorUmar IIworked out a compromise in which, beginning from 719, land from whichkharajwas paid could not be transferred to Muslims; instead, they could lease such land, but in that case they would be required to paykharajfrom it. With the passage of time, the practical result of that reform was thatkharajwas levied on most land without regard for the cultivator's religion. The reforms of Umar II were finalized under theAbbasidsand would thereafter form the model of tax systems in the Islamic state.[3]From that time on,kharajwas also used as a general term describing all kinds of taxes: for example, the classic treatise on taxation by the 9th century juristAbu Yusufwas calledKitab al-Kharaj,i.e.The Book On Taxation.[2]

20th-century Russian orientalist, A. Yu. Yakubovski, compares the land tax system ofPersianSassanidswith that of the post-IslamicCaliphateera:

A comparison between pre-Islamic documents and those of the Islamic period reveals that conquering Arabs increased the land taxation without exception. Thus, raising taxes of each acre of wheat field to four dirhams and each acre of barley field to two dirhams, whereas during reign ofKhosro Anushiravanit used to be a single dirham for each acre of wheat or barley field. During the later stage of theUmayyad Caliphate,landowners were paying from one fourth to one third of their land produce to the state askharaj.[4]

In theOttoman Empire,kharajevolved intoharaç,a form of poll tax on non-Muslim subjects. It was superseded bycizye.[citation needed]

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^Böwering, Gerhard, ed. (2013).The Princeton Encyclopedia of Islamic Political Thought.Princeton University Press. p. 545.ISBN978-0691134840.
  2. ^abLewis (2002), p. 72
  3. ^Lewis (2002), p. 79–80
  4. ^N. V. Pigulevskaya, A. Yu. Yakubovski, I. P. Petrushevski, L. V. Stroeva, A. M. Belenitski. The History of Iran from Ancient Times to the End of Eighteenth Century (in Persian), Tehran, 1967, p. 161.

References

[edit]
  • Cooper, Richard S. "The Assessment and Collection of Kharaj Tax in Medieval Egypt",Journal of the American Oriental Society,Vol. 96, No. 3. (Jul. – Sep., 1976), pp. 365–382.
  • Cummings, John Thomas; Askari, Hossein; Mustafa, Ahmad. "Islam and Modern Economic Change" in Esposito, 1980, pp. 25–47
  • Esposito, John L. (ed.).Islam and Development: Religion and Sociopolitical Change(Syracuse, NY, Syracuse University Press, 1980)
  • Gaudefroy-Demombynes, Maurice(tr. John P. MacGregor).Muslim Institutions(London, Allen & Unwin, 1950)
  • Hourani, Albert,A History of the Arab Peoples(Cambridge, MA: Belknap-Harvard University Press, 1991)
  • Melis, Nicola, "Il concetto di ğihād", in P. Manduchi (a cura di),Dalla penna al mouse. Gli strumenti di diffusione del concetto di gihad,Angeli, Milano 2006, pp. 23–54.
  • Melis, Nicola, "Lo statuto giuridico degli ebrei dell'Impero Ottomano", in M. Contu – N. Melis - G. Pinna (a cura di),Ebraismo e rapporti con le culture del Mediterraneo nei secoli XVIII-XX,Giuntina, Firenze 2003.
  • Melis, Nicola,Trattato sulla guerra. Il Kitāb al-ğihād di Molla Hüsrev,Aipsa, Cagliari 2002.
  • Hawting, G. R.The First Dynasty of Islam: The Umayyad Caliphate AD 661-750(London, Routledge, 2000)
  • Lambton, Ann K. S.Landlord and Peasant in Persia: A Study of Land Tenure and Land Revenue Administration(London, Oxford University Press, 1953)
  • Lewis, Bernard (2002).The Arabs in History.Oxford: Oxford University Press.ISBN0-19-280310-7.
  • Poliak, A. N. "Classification of Lands in the Islamic Law and Its Technical Terms".The American Journal of Semitic Languages and Literatures,Vol. 57, No. 1. (Jan., 1940), pp. 50–62.
  • Stillman, Norman (1979).The Jews of Arab Lands: A History and Source Book.Philadelphia: Jewish Publication Society of America.ISBN0-8276-0116-6.
  • Watt, W. Montgomery.Islamic Political Thought: The Basic Concepts(Edinburgh, Edinburgh University Press, 1980)
[edit]